Littérature scientifique sur le sujet « NO producer »

Créez une référence correcte selon les styles APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard et plusieurs autres

Choisissez une source :

Consultez les listes thématiques d’articles de revues, de livres, de thèses, de rapports de conférences et d’autres sources académiques sur le sujet « NO producer ».

À côté de chaque source dans la liste de références il y a un bouton « Ajouter à la bibliographie ». Cliquez sur ce bouton, et nous générerons automatiquement la référence bibliographique pour la source choisie selon votre style de citation préféré : APA, MLA, Harvard, Vancouver, Chicago, etc.

Vous pouvez aussi télécharger le texte intégral de la publication scolaire au format pdf et consulter son résumé en ligne lorsque ces informations sont inclues dans les métadonnées.

Articles de revues sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

Radchenko, M. M., H. S. Andriiash, N. Y. Beiko, O. O. Tigunova et S. M. Shulga. « Bacillus subtilis strain producer preparation with increased accumulation of riboflavin ». Faktori eksperimental'noi evolucii organizmiv 31 (1 septembre 2022) : 77–82. http://dx.doi.org/10.7124/feeo.v31.1488.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Aim. The increasing of riboflavin accumulation by chemical mutagenesis of Bacillus subtilis IMB B-7797 strain producer was the aim of this work. Methods. We used the method of treating the strain producer with a chemical mutagen N-methyl-N-nitro-N-nitrosoguanidine to achieve this goal and followed by culturing the resulting clone and determining the accumulation of riboflavin. Results. B. subtilis IFBG NTG2 mutant strain producer which differed in morphological characteristics (color, size, colony shape) and riboflavin accumulation from the original culture as a result of chemical mutagen action on B. subtilis IMB B-7797 was obtained. Conclusions. B. subtilis IFBG NTG2 mutant strain producer as a result of action on B. subtilis IMB B-7797 by chemical mutagen and which differed in morphological features (color, size, colony shape) and riboflavin accumulation from the original culture. was obtained, B. subtilis IFBG NTG2 strain producer, which produced riboflavin amount of 14.8 g/dm3, which is 9% more than produced by the original B. subtilis IMB B-7797 strain producer was obtained by chemical mutagenesis. B. subtilis IFBG NTG2 strain produser is further proposed for use in industrial technology of riboflavin and creation of a recombinant strain produser for synthesis of riboflavin.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Morgan, Richard G., et Brian T. O'Reilly. « Producer column : Order 451 decision's effect on producers ». Natural Gas 6, no 5 (16 avril 2008) : 8–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/gas.3410060504.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

O'Reilly, Brian T. « Producer demand charges demand producer protests ». Natural Gas 7, no 6 (20 août 2008) : 14–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/gas.3410070605.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Gaetano, Arianne. « Migration and Modernization in China ». Transfers 4, no 3 (1 décembre 2014) : 126–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.3167/trans.2014.040312.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Last Train Home (guitu lieche 归途列车) 2009. Produced by Mila Aung-Th win and Daniel Cross (executive producers) with Bob Moore (co-producer) and Zhao Qi (executive producer). Directed by Lixin Fan. Documentary. Cast: Changhua Zhan, Suqin Chen, Qin Zhang, Yang Zhang, Tingsui Tang (as themselves).
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

English, Burton C., Robin L. Graham, Jose Velasquez, Vickie Witcher et James A. Larson. « Evaluation of agricultural producer willingness to produce biomass ». International Advances in Economic Research 2, no 1 (février 1996) : 99. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf02295178.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Benham, William T. « Producer rate proposal : Producer point of view ». Natural Gas 16, no 7 (9 janvier 2007) : 24–26. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/gas.3410160706.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Olsen, M., P. Johnsson, T. Möller, R. Paladino et M. Lindblad. « Aspergillus nomius, an important aflatoxin producer in Brazil nuts ? » World Mycotoxin Journal 1, no 2 (1 mai 2008) : 123–26. http://dx.doi.org/10.3920/wmj2008.1032.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
The relationship between aflatoxin B1 and G1 was examined in samples from 199 aflatoxin contaminated lots of inshell Brazil nuts imported to Europe. In most of the samples, the relationship between B1 and G1 were approximately 50/50 indicating that the major responsible aflatoxin producing fungi cannot be Aspergillus flavus, which produces solely B aflatoxins. Fungal strains were isolated from two batches of Brazil nuts and isolates of both A. nomius and A. flavus could be identified. The A. nomius isolates were good producers of both B and G aflatoxins, while the A. flavus strains only produced B aflatoxins. In conclusion, this study suggests that A. nomius is an important producer of aflatoxins in Brazil nuts and that its occurrence, and possibly other B and G aflatoxin producers, should be further examined since this may influence strategies for prevention and control of aflatoxins in Brazil nuts.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

SHUKLA, ADITYA, et Ramchandra Ramchandra. « A Study on Economics of Marketing and Production of Aonla in District Pratapgarh (U.P.) ». International Journal of Advances in Agricultural Science and Technology 8, no 9 (30 septembre 2021) : 142–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.47856/ijaast.2021.v08i9.016.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
The study was conducted, in Pratapgarh district of Uttar Pradesh. Random sampling technique was used for the selection of blocks, villages and proportionate random sampling for selection of growers. From the list, 200 growers were selected, using proportionate sampling method i.e. 90 small, 70 medium and 40 large farmers respectively. The primary data were collected from the respondents by using interview schedule, while secondary data were collected from the official records, published data, magazines etc. The marketable surplus for Aonla in the area was found to be 140, 160 and 180 quintals per farm which constituting (99.10%), (99.48%) and (99.48%) to their total Aonla production. Channel-I, Marketing cost when producers sold their produce to consumer in the market was Rs.90/quintal. Net price received by the producer is 410/quintal. Producer share in consumer price was 82 per cent. Price spread is Rs 90. Marketing efficiency was 5.55 per cent. Channel-II, Marketing cost when producers sold their produce to retailers was Rs.105/quintal. Among these cost transportation charges was most important which accounted for Rs.15/quintal, followed by loading and unloading cost Rs.10/quintal, market cost Rs.10/quintal, labour cost was Rs.10/quintal and miscellaneous cost Rs.50/quintal respectively. Sale price of the producer to retailer was Rs.500/quintals inn different farms size group. Channel-III, this is identified as the longest channel. The producer sells his produce to the commission agents, who in turn sell it to retailer in the market. Finally, the produce reaches to the consumer after collecting margin. Average marketing cost when producer sold their produce to commission agents, in the market was Rs.165. Among these grading, cleaning etc. was Rs. 10 and 10 per Qts. loading and unloading cost Rs. 10 per Qtl. Transportation cost Rs. 20per Qts, Miscellaneous charges Rs. 25/qts, respectively.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Kalashnikov, Vitaliy, Daniel Flores Curiel et Vyacheslav V. Kalashnikov. « Production Competition in Electricity Sector : Social Welfare vs. Managerial Incentives in a Partially Regulated Duopoly ». Journal of Advanced Computational Intelligence and Intelligent Informatics 21, no 6 (20 octobre 2017) : 1034–39. http://dx.doi.org/10.20965/jaciii.2017.p1034.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
We study production competition between two electricity producers, where one of them is subject to a nationalization decision and the other is a private producer that chooses managerial incentives to counter governmental actions. The government wants to maximize a modified form of social welfare and chooses partial nationalization, which still has a serious impact on the rival private producer. We find, that by offering managerial incentives the private producer recovers its lost profit and induces even less nationalization. We also find that such equilibrium might produce the same level of social welfare than one without incentives.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

Beyers, William B. « Producer services ». Progress in Human Geography 16, no 4 (octobre 1992) : 573–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/030913259201600407.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.

Thèses sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

Waldon, Tracy Charles. « Urban Producer Theory ». Thesis, The George Washington University, 2013. http://pqdtopen.proquest.com/#viewpdf?dispub=3590578.

Texte intégral
Résumé :

Urban producer theory introduces a production function which incorporates congestion in production with inputs possessing a quality component that influences productivity. These features yield cost-minimizing behavior in which firms respond to higher space rent by increasing the quality of the inputs used in production. This behavior generates demand-side sorting of high quality inputs into high rent areas. The prediction of sorting based on input quality is tested on attorneys employed in the Cleveland CBSA. Evidence of the sorting into high rent areas of attorneys based upon the national ranking of the law school attended is found. A 1% increase in rent leads to a 1.26% to 2.89% increase in the number of the highest quality attorneys employed in high rent districts. Ability sorting poses a significant risk in biasing the measurement of agglomeration economies based on wages.

Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Salisbury, Karli A. « Examining Market Channels for Local Produce : Consumer Affordability and Producer Profitability ». DigitalCommons@USU, 2018. https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/etd/7408.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
This study examines the price differences of commonly consumed produce between farmers’ markets and grocery stores in Utah. Our first objective is to compare price differences of a basket of produce between farmers’ markets and grocery stores. We compare these price differences in terms of low-income consumer affordability and if an individual can afford a market basket of produce using a combination of Farmers’ Market Nutrition Program (FMNP) dollars and Double Up Food Bucks (DUFB) incentive dollars. Our second objective for this study is to establish the price premiums of individual produce items based on where the produce was sold, time of season, market channel (farmers’ market versus grocery store), as well as production method used (conventional versus organic). The findings from this research can inform policy makers of the affordability of farmers’ market produce and apply incentive programs more effectively. We can inform consumers of the price differences so they can maximize their food budgets. We can use the research to help producers make market strategies that can then maximize their profits.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

Alev, Isil. « Operational perspectives on extended producer responsibility for durable and consumable products ». Diss., Georgia Institute of Technology, 2015. http://hdl.handle.net/1853/54382.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
This thesis consists of three essays that contribute to the understanding of the economic implications of Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) for certain durable (e.g. electronics) and consumable (e.g. pharmaceuticals) products from an operational perspective. In the first essay, we investigate the effect of EPR-based policy on a durable good producer’s secondary market strategy. Our analysis uncovers possible strategic approach of durable good producers to EPR obligations, which may result in unintended outcomes. We provide insights into how to set EPR obligations to avoid these adverse outcomes. In the second essay, we examine the operational details of market-based EPR implementation on the ground. We analyze whether the advocated premises of the marked-based approach hold by focusing on the Minnesota Electronics Recycling Act. Based on evaluation reports and stakeholder interviews, we find that the Minnesota Act achieves the premises of the market-based approach, but this occurs at the expense of several unintended outcomes, following unforeseen market dynamics and associated stakeholder interactions. In the third essay, we explore how the EPR-based policies can be effectively operationalized for managing pharmaceutical overage by analyzing the interactions between major stakeholders and moderating factors for these interactions. We demonstrate that the preferred policy depends on the healthcare and externality characteristics of the medicine together with collection-related requirements. Additionally, we investigate the perspectives of pharmaceutical stakeholders on the policy choice and identify the influential factors in this context.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Houtman, Martijn. « Nonparametric consumer and producer analysis ». [Maastricht : Maastricht : Rijksuniversiteit Limburg] ; University Library, Maastricht University [Host], 1995. http://arno.unimaas.nl/show.cgi?fid=5770.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

Augusteijn, Michael J. (Michael James) 1974. « Extended producer responsibility and comparative advantage ». Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1999. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/9560.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Thesis (S.M.)--Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Sloan School of Management, Technology and Policy Program, 1999.
Includes bibliographical references (p. 110-114).
Extended producer responsibility is a business strategy whereby a firm assumes responsibility for the environmental impacts of a product throughout its entire lifecycle. By taking such responsibility, a firm realizes an incentive to design environmentally preferable products that are easier to recycle, reuse, or re-manufacture. Many extended producer responsibility strategies involve product take-back, whereby the producer can harvest residual value of the product at the end of its useful lifetime. This strategy is connected to sustainable development in that producers are taking responsibility for the products they are offering. Society is faced with many global environmental problems that threaten ecological stability and social wellbeing. Extended producer responsibility facilitates awareness of these problems and encourages the design of innovative products with minimal environmental impacts. This awareness is an important step toward the possibility of sustainable development. There are three requirements for successful differentiation of a product. First, consumers must be willing to pay for the new product. Second, credible information must be available regarding the product. Third, barriers must be erected to prevent competitors from imitating the product. A producer who attempts to satisfy these requirements is exhibiting rational economic behavior. Hence, this thesis asks whether firms that invest in sustainable product differentiation through extended producer responsibility are exhibiting rational economic behavior. Four products are examined in extensive detail. These include Xerox's Document Center 265, Interface's environmental flooring products including the Evergreen Lease, Kodak's single use camera, and Deep E. Co.' s environmental footwear. Each case study has shown evidence of rational economic behavior. However, Interface and Deep E. Co. have also displayed strong environmental propensities that seem to prohibit successful differentiation. Furthermore, two other requirements are found that are particularly important for extended producer responsibility. First, the producer must invest in an extensive R&D relationship with its suppliers. Second, to harvest residual value of the product, reverse logistics systems must be in place. The thesis concludes that regulation is not necessary for products such as those studied here. However, voluntary programs resembling EPA's Energy Star program may help in communicating the benefits of extended producer responsibility to other businesses.
by Michael J. Augusteijn.
S.M.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Fischer, Manfred M. « The Economic Role of Producer Services ». WU Vienna University of Economics and Business, 1990. http://epub.wu.ac.at/4228/1/WSG_DP_0590.pdf.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Juleff, Linda E. « Advanced producer services and urban growth ». Thesis, Sheffield Hallam University, 1989. http://shura.shu.ac.uk/19889/.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Service industries have traditionally been viewed as secondary to, and at best supportive of, manufacturing industries. This thesis is designed to challenge this view with regard to a particular group of services, advanced producer services. It contends that this group makes both direct and indirect contributions to economic growth at urban region level by operating in two ways: firstly, by providing intermediate inputs into the production of finished products and secondly, in its own right, selling its services to clients outside of the region. This contradicts the expectations of theoretical models of urban growth such as export base theory which cast services in an entirely dependent role. Analysis of the spatial distribution of advanced producer services reveals a significant degree of regional inequality in their provision which given the contribution they make to growth has potentially serious implications for the economic regeneration of many of Britain's depressed areas.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

Muir, Pete. « The art of the record producer ». Thesis, Queensland University of Technology, 1999.

Trouver le texte intégral
Résumé :
The record producer has played an extensive role in the development of music aesthetics since the 1950's yet has remained virtually anonymous, save for a few notable exceptions. In this time, producers have developed an art form that exists within the design, capture and rendering of sound. This art form is distinct from the music composition and performance and should receive appropriate acknowledgment. This paper identifies the defining factors of art. These elements are explored through theoretical and practical discussions to establish the artistic contributions of the producer. Through the use of technique - the producer's craft in recording technology, and through the use of form - the producer's design of various layers of recording from composition to mastering, they control the artistic outcomes of the record, which ultimately impact aesthetically on the listener. Therefore the producer is indeed an artist.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Hienerth, Christoph, Christopher Lettl et Peter Keinz. « Synergies among Producer Firms, Lead Users, and User Communities : The Case of the LEGO Producer-User Ecosystem ». Wiley-Blackwell, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12127.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
While many firms today proactively involve users in their new product development efforts using a wide variety of methods such as the lead user method, firm-hosted user communities, or mass customization toolkits, some pioneering firms are experimenting with the creation of sustainable producer-user ecosystems designed for the continuous exploration and exploitation of business opportunities. In this paper, the functioning of such ecosystems is studied with particular emphasis on the synergies they can yield. Based on an explorative and longitudinal multiple case study design, the producer-user ecosystem of the firm LEGO is analyzed, and three main actors in the ecosystem are identified: entrepreneurial lead users who aim to start their own businesses, a vibrant user community, and the LEGO company as the focal producer firm and facilitator for multiple user-to-user and user-to-producer interactions. Our study reveals three kinds of synergies: (1) reduced risk for entrepreneurial lead users and the focal producer firm, (2) the extension of the design space of the focal producer firm's products, and (3) the creation of buzz within the user community. Finally, the theoretical and managerial implications of our findings for innovation researchers and practitioners are discussed. (authors' abstract)
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

Gottberg, Annika. « Producer responsibility for WEEE as a driver of ecodesign : Case studies of business responses to producer responsibility charges ». Thesis, Cranfield University, 2003. http://hdl.handle.net/1826/745.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Due to potential environmental, resource and health problems associated with waste, waste minimisation is a prioritised waste management strategy in many countries. Producer responsibility policies promote waste minimisation by stipulating separate collection and recycling of particular waste streams. In addition, a purpose of the policy is to encourage product development that reduces waste generation and improves recyclability. It is sometimes assumed that the financial responsibility assigned to producers for collection and recycling of their end-of-life products will instigate waste minimising product development in order to reduce costs. However, this view has also been contested. Following the adoption of the WEEE Directive (2002/96/EC) all EU member states have to implement producer responsibility for WEEE. Taking a qualitative multiple case study approach, this study explores company responses to the costs of existing national producer responsibility policies for WEEE in relation product development. The purpose is to inform policy-making on the effectiveness of producer responsibility charges in achieving waste minimising product development. The study comprises both large companies and SMEs in the lighting equipments sector. It also includes companies in EU member states without producer responsibility for WEEE in order to see if there are any differences in waste-minimising product design among countries and if national policies have an impact beyond national borders. Economic principles and previous research findings on ecodesign make up the analytical framework for the study. Quantitative data on cost-benefits of ecodesign and waste minimisation achievements were scarce. However, the company responses show that the costs imposed on the producers by the WEEE policy have had little effect on product development so far. The costs can generally be transferred to customers via product prices. The price increases were generally small and without any negative effects on competitiveness. Other drivers such as bans on certain substances, environmental industry product declarations, commercial advantages including direct customer demands from for instance public procurers, are more effective.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.

Livres sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

Vonnegut, Norb. Top producer. Waterville, Me : Thorndike Press, 2009.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Top producer. Waterville, Me : Thorndike Press/Gale, 2009.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

Vonnegut, Norb. Top producer. Waterville, Me : Thorndike Press/Gale, 2009.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Music producer. Ann Arbor, Mich : Cherry Lake Pub., 2012.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

R, Gerritse, et Instituut voor Onderzoek van Overheidsuitgaven (Hague, Netherlands), dir. Producer subsidies. London : Pinter, 1990.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Wooster, Patricia. Music producer. Ann Arbor, Mich : Cherry Lake Pub., 2012.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Brian, McKernan, dir. Producer to producer : Insider tips for entertainment media. 2e éd. Studio City, Calif : Michael Wiese Productions, 1997.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

Muchnik, Federico. The Strategic Producer. New York : Routledge, 2016. : Routledge, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781315648729.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Council of Petroleum Accountants Societies (U.S.). Producer gas imbalances. Tulsa, Okla. (P.O. Box 800, Tulsa 74101) : Kraftbilt Products, 1991.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Statistics Directorate., dir. Producer price indices. Paris : Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 1994.

Trouver le texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.

Chapitres de livres sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

Weik, Martin H. « producer ». Dans Computer Science and Communications Dictionary, 1344. Boston, MA : Springer US, 2000. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/1-4020-0613-6_14792.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Gooch, Jan W. « Producer ». Dans Encyclopedic Dictionary of Polymers, 917. New York, NY : Springer New York, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6247-8_14572.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

Novy, Ari, et Latha Nagarajan. « Producer Choice ». Dans Socio-Economic Considerations in Biotechnology Regulation, 229–46. New York, NY : Springer New York, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-9440-9_16.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Wang, Susheng. « Producer Theory ». Dans Microeconomic Theory, 3–36. Singapore : Springer Singapore, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-0041-7_1.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

Gooch, Jan W. « Producer-Colored ». Dans Encyclopedic Dictionary of Polymers, 591. New York, NY : Springer New York, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6247-8_9493.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Gooch, Jan W. « Producer Twist ». Dans Encyclopedic Dictionary of Polymers, 591. New York, NY : Springer New York, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6247-8_9496.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Jackson, Brian M. « Producer Tips ». Dans The Music Producer’s Survival Guide, 191–237. Second edition. | New York, NY : Routledge, 2018. | Series : Sound on sound presents : Routledge, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781315519777-7.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

Stewart, Peter. « The producer ». Dans The Live-Streaming Handbook, 273–76. London ; New York : Routledge, 2018. : Routledge, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781315209883-21.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Mulhearn, Chris, et Howard R. Vane. « The Producer ». Dans Economics, 71–83. London : Macmillan Education UK, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-14437-2_4.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

Turvey, Ralph. « Producer Demand ». Dans Demand and Supply, 39–46. London : Routledge, 2022. http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781003283225-3.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.

Actes de conférences sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

Ardi, Romadhani, et B. Handoko Purwojatmiko. « Producer Perspective on Extended Producer Responsibility Concept ». Dans ICIBE 2019 : 2019 The 5th International Conference on Industrial and Business Engineering. New York, NY, USA : ACM, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1145/3364335.3364341.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Schmid, Klaus, et Holger Eichelberger. « EASy-Producer ». Dans SPLC '15 : 2015 International Conference on Software Product Lines. New York, NY, USA : ACM, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1145/2791060.2791112.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

Eichelberger, Holger, Sascha El-Sharkawy, Christian Kröher et Klaus Schmid. « EASy-producer ». Dans the 18th International Software Product Line Conference. New York, New York, USA : ACM Press, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1145/2647908.2655979.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Schmid, Klaus, et Holger Eichelberger. « EASy-producer ». Dans SPLC '16 : The 20th International Systems and Software Product Line Conference. New York, NY, USA : ACM, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.1145/2934466.2956657.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

Eichelberger, Holger, et Klaus Schmid. « EASy-Producer - A Product Line Production Environment ». Dans 2008 12th International Software Product Line Conference (SPLC). IEEE, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/splc.2008.24.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Hoffenson, Steven, et Rikard Söderberg. « Policy and Demand as Drivers for Product Quality and Sustainability : A Market Systems Approach ». Dans ASME 2014 International Design Engineering Technical Conferences and Computers and Information in Engineering Conference. American Society of Mechanical Engineers, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1115/detc2014-34368.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
The market is a complex system with many different stakeholders and interactions. A number of decisions within this system affect the design of new products, not only from design teams but also from consumers, producers, and policy-makers. Market systems studies have shown how profit-optimal producer decisions regarding product design and pricing can influence a number of different factors including the quality, environmental impact, production costs, and ultimately consumer demand for the product. This study models the ways that policies and consumer demand combine in a market systems framework to influence optimal product design and, in particular, product quality and environmental sustainability. Implementing this model for the design of a mobile phone case shows how different environmental impact assessment methods, levels of taxation, and factors introduced to the consumer decision-making process will influence producer profits and overall environmental impacts. This demonstrates how different types of policies might be evaluated for their effectiveness in achieving economic success for the producer and reduced environmental impacts for society, and a “win-win” scenario was uncovered in the case of the mobile phone.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Fukuda, Shuichi. « Best for Whom ? Changing Design for Creative Customers ». Dans ASME 2010 International Design Engineering Technical Conferences and Computers and Information in Engineering Conference. ASMEDC, 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1115/detc2010-28330.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Our traditional design has been producer-centric. But to respond to the frequent and extensive changes and increasing diversification, we have to change our design to user-centric. But it is not a straightforward extension and just listening to the voice of the customer is not enough. Value is defined as value = performance/cost, but performance has been interpreted in the current design solely as functions of a final product and all other factors such as manufacturing are considered as cost. This framework has been effective until recently because there has been asymmetry of information between the producer and the customer. As the producer had a greater amount of information, they only had to produce a product which they think best and it really satisfied the customer who needed a product. The 20th century was the age of products. But as we approached the 21st century, we entered information society and sometimes the customer knows more than the producer. Thus, such a one way flow of development to fill the information (water level) gap doe not work any more, because the gap is quickly disappearing. The difference was evaluated as value in the traditional design and it meant profit for the producer. Therefore, a new approach to create value is called for. One solution is to raise the water level together by the producer and the customer so that the level increase serves for profit for the producer and for the true value for the customer. In order to achieve this goal, we have to identify what is the true value for the customer. We have to step outside of our traditional notion of value being functions of a final product. What is the true value for the customer? It is customers’ satisfaction. Then, how can we satisfy our customers. This paper points out if we note that our customers are very active and creative, we can provide satisfaction to them by getting them involved in the whole process of product development. Then our customers can enjoy not only product experience but also process experience, which will satisfy their needs for self actualization and challenge, i.e., their highest human needs.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

« LOCATING AND EXTRACTING PRODUCT SPECIFICATIONS FROM PRODUCER WEBSITES ». Dans 12th International Conference on Enterprise Information Systems. SciTePress - Science and and Technology Publications, 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.5220/0002874300130022.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Zadbood, Amineh, et Steven Hoffenson. « Agent-Based Modeling of Automobile Producer and Consumer Behavior to Support Design for Market Systems Analysis ». Dans ASME 2017 International Design Engineering Technical Conferences and Computers and Information in Engineering Conference. American Society of Mechanical Engineers, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.1115/detc2017-68351.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Improving design for market systems analysis relies on understanding the motivations and interactions among producers and consumers. Producers should theoretically develop their strategies for designing new products based on consumer demand and the expected profits from their sales. In this study, an agent-based modeling approach is proposed to simulate consumer and producer behavior for use in market systems analysis, and it is demonstrated through a simplified automobile market. In the model, consumers make heterogeneous purchasing decisions based on product attributes, which provides the producers with insights into their preferences and how to improve upon these design attributes over time. Emergent behavior of the model shows that analyzing the behavior of consumers provides the opportunity for producers to compete which one another with different strategies to improve their designs by investing in technology improvements. This lays the foundation for future work that can model how different business and regulatory strategies, social structures, and policies influence consumer and producer behavior, which in turn influences economic, environmental, and social impacts.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

CORDERO, RUBÉN, et EFRAíN ROJAS. « A PRODUCER OF UNIVERSES ». Dans Proceedings of 2002 International Conference. WORLD SCIENTIFIC, 2006. http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/9789812772732_0011.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.

Rapports d'organisations sur le sujet "NO producer"

1

De Salvo, Carmine Paolo, Gonzalo Muñoz, Juan José Egas et Olga Shik. Producer Support Estimate (PSE). Inter-American Development Bank, septembre 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.18235/0001881.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
2

Lain, Justin, Daryl R. Strohbehn, Dennis DeWitt, Russ Euken, Denise Schwab et Daniel D. Loy. A Producer Survey of Feeding Corn Co-Products in Iowa. Ames (Iowa) : Iowa State University, janvier 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.31274/ans_air-180814-424.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
3

Mills, Stephanie E., et Andrew Rupke. Critical Minerals of Utah, Second Edition. Utah Geological Survey, mars 2023. http://dx.doi.org/10.34191/c-135.

Texte intégral
Résumé :
Utah is a state with diverse geology and natural resources, and this diversity extends to mineral resources that are deemed critical by the U.S. Department of the Interior. Utah’s critical mineral portfolio includes current producers, known resources, areas of past production, and undeveloped occurrences. This report, now in its second edition, summarizes the geographic and geologic distribution of critical minerals within Utah. Utah is notable for being the global leader in beryllium production; being the only domestic producer of magnesium metal; being one of only two states producing lithium (as of publication); and being a byproduct producer of tellurium, platinum, and palladium from the world-class Bingham Canyon mine, which is one of only two domestic tellurium producers. Utah has known resources of aluminum, fluorspar, germanium, gallium, indium, vanadium, and zinc, as well as past production and occurrences of many other critical minerals. In total, Utah currently produces 6 critical minerals, has known resources of 7 more, and hosts an additional 27 as past producers and/or occurrences with limited potential for economic development.
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
4

Bentley, Jennifer A., Larry F. Tranel, Leo L. Timms et Kristen Schulte. Automatic Milking Systems (AMS)—Producer Surveys. Ames (Iowa) : Iowa State University, janvier 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.31274/ans_air-180814-739.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
5

Tranel, Larry F., Jennifer A. Bentley, Leo L. Timms et Kristen Schulte. Low Cost Milking Parlors—Producer Surveys. Ames (Iowa) : Iowa State University, janvier 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.31274/ans_air-180814-915.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
6

Wheeler, Christopher H. Worker Turnover, Industry Localization, and Producer Size. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2004. http://dx.doi.org/10.20955/wp.2004.021.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
7

Kliebenstein, James B., Jeffery C. Lorimor et Benjamin Larson. Pork Producer Efforts to Improve Neighbor Relations. Ames (Iowa) : Iowa State University, janvier 2004. http://dx.doi.org/10.31274/ans_air-180814-182.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
8

Bentley, Jenn A., Leo L. Timms, Larry F. Tranel et Ron A. Lenth. Manure Management Systems-Iowa Dairy Producer Surveys. Ames (Iowa) : Iowa State University, janvier 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.31274/ans_air-180814-204.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
9

Shiferaw, Bekele, G. A. Obare et Geoffrey Muricho. Rural institutions and producer organizations in imperfect markets : experiences from producer marketing groups in semi-arid eastern Kenya. Washington, DC : International Food Policy Research Institute, 2006. http://dx.doi.org/10.2499/capriwp60.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
10

Das, Sanghamitra, Mark Roberts et James Tybout. Market Entry Costs, Producer Heterogeneity, and Export Dynamics. Cambridge, MA : National Bureau of Economic Research, décembre 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w8629.

Texte intégral
Styles APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, etc.
Nous offrons des réductions sur tous les plans premium pour les auteurs dont les œuvres sont incluses dans des sélections littéraires thématiques. Contactez-nous pour obtenir un code promo unique!

Vers la bibliographie