Academic literature on the topic 'RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS'
Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles
Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS.'
Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.
You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.
Journal articles on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
od G. Bhongade, Kunal M. Lokhande, Vin. "Transmission Congestion Management in Restructured Power Systems." International Journal of Advanced Research in Electrical, Electronics and Instrumentation Engineering 04, no. 07 (July 20, 2015): 5977–85. http://dx.doi.org/10.15662/ijareeie.2015.0407023.
Full textPai, M. A. "Operation of restructured power systems [Book Review]." IEEE Power Engineering Review 21, no. 12 (December 2001): 48–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/mper.2001.969600.
Full textConejo, A. J., R. Garcia-Bertrand, and M. Diaz-Salazar. "Generation Maintenance Scheduling in Restructured Power Systems." IEEE Transactions on Power Systems 20, no. 2 (May 2005): 984–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/tpwrs.2005.846078.
Full textRamesh, Guguloth, and T. K. Sunil Kumar. "Optimal power flow-based congestion management in restructured power systems." International Journal of Power and Energy Conversion 7, no. 1 (2016): 84. http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/ijpec.2016.075067.
Full textNargėlas, A. "Automatic Generation Control in Restructured Electric Power Systems." IFAC Proceedings Volumes 33, no. 12 (June 2000): 233–36. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s1474-6670(17)37316-0.
Full textAmelink, H. "Power systems engineers in the restructured utility industry." IEEE Computer Applications in Power 14, no. 1 (January 2001): 10–12. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/mcap.2001.893349.
Full textDing, Yi, Peng Wang, and Anatoly Lisnianski. "Optimal reserve management for restructured power generating systems." Reliability Engineering & System Safety 91, no. 7 (July 2006): 792–99. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ress.2005.08.001.
Full textLiu, F., Y. H. Song, J. Ma, S. Mei, and Q. Lu. "Optimal load-frequency control in restructured power systems." IEE Proceedings - Generation, Transmission and Distribution 150, no. 1 (2003): 87. http://dx.doi.org/10.1049/ip-gtd:20020683.
Full textKheradmandi, Morteza, Mehdi Ehsan, René Feuillet, and Nouredine Hadj-Saied. "Rescheduling of power systems constrained with transient stability limits in restructured power systems." Electric Power Systems Research 81, no. 1 (January 2011): 1–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.epsr.2010.07.008.
Full textBhatt, Praghnesh, Ranjit Roy, and S. P. Ghoshal. "Optimized multi area AGC simulation in restructured power systems." International Journal of Electrical Power & Energy Systems 32, no. 4 (May 2010): 311–22. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijepes.2009.09.002.
Full textDissertations / Theses on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
Petoussis, Savvas G. "Optimisation of restructured power systems." Thesis, University of Warwick, 2006. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.443311.
Full textDoorman, Gerard. "Peaking Capacity in Restructured Power Systems." Doctoral thesis, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Faculty of Information Technology, Mathematics and Electrical Engineering, 2000. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:no:ntnu:diva-493.
Full textThe theme of this thesis is the supply of capacity during peak demand in restructured power systems. There are a number of reasons why there is uncertainty about whether an enegyonly electricity market (where generators are only paid for the energy produced) is able to ensure uninterrupted supply during peak load conditions.
Much of the public debate in Europe has been about the present surplus generation capacity. However, in a truly competitive environment, it is hard to believe that seldom used capacity will be kept operational. This is illustrated by developments in Sweden. For this reason, the large surplus of generation capacity in the European Union may vanish much faster than generally assumed. In the USA, much of the debate has been about California. During the last three summers, California has occasionally experienced involuntary load shedding and prices have been very high during these periods. To some extent, the Californian situation illustrates the relevance of the subject of this thesis: in a deregulated system generators may not be willing to invest in peaking capacity that is only needed occasionally, even though prices are very high during these periods.
A good solution to the problem of providing peaking power is pivotal to the success of power market restructuring. Solutions that fail to create the right incentives will result in unacceptable load shedding and can endanger the whole restructuring process. On the other hand, solutions that pay too much for investments in peaking power will lead to generation capacity surpluses and thus represent a societal loss.
Why is peaking capacity a problematic issue in energy-only markets?
Traditionally, probabilistic methods are applied to calculate the required generation capacity to obtain a desired level of reliability. In a centrally planned system, this level of generation capacity is developed in a least-cost manner. A single utility or central authorities can thus control the level of reliability directly. This is not possible in a market-based system, if suppliers are only paid for the energy produced.
Under the assumption of certainty and continually varying prices, generators fully recover their variable and investment costs under ideal market conditions. When uncertainty is taken into account, generators will cover their expected costs. However, revenues will be extremely volatile, especially for peaking generators. Combined with a risk-averse attitude, it is unlikely that investments will be sufficient to maintain the traditional level of reliability in an energyonly market. Consequently, one would expect reserve margins to decline in such markets. This effect is very clear in Sweden that deregulated in 1996, and less explicit in a number of other cases like Norway, California and Alberta.
Pricing and Consumer Preferences
The theory of electricity pricing was originally developed for vertically integrated utilities, but elements from this theory are also valuable in a restructured context. Many authors have agreed on the presence of a capacity element in the optimal price during peak-load conditions, while price should equal marginal cost during low-load conditions. An important assumption is that prices have to be stable. More recently, spot pricing of electricity has been advocated. A number of papers have been written about how to efficiently include security considerations in the spot price.
Because the availability of capacity cannot be directly controlled in an energy-only spot market, the probability of occasional capacity shortages increases. It is important to be prepared for this situation. The core of the problem is that demand is de facto inelastic in the short-term because of traditional tariff systems. It is shown that considerable economic gains are obtained when demand elasticity can be utilized, even if only minor shares of demand are elastic in the short-term. Better utilization of demand elasticity was also profitable in traditional systems, but after restructuring the gain is much larger: the alternative is not expensive generation but random rationing, which is unacceptable in modern society.
It is possible to go one step further. Consumers have different preferences for the use of energy and reliability. Some consumers have a low tolerance about being disconnected, while others are more willing to accept this. This will be reflected by their willingness to pay for reliability. A better solution would emerge if consumers could buy electricity and reliability more or less as separate commodities, based on their preferences.
In the context of pricing it should be pointed out that ”profile-based settlement” that allows small consumers to freely choose their supplier without hourly metering is detrimental with respect to the correct pricing of capacity. It should only be used in the initial phases of opening a market.
Improved utilization of system resources
Even in the short-term, demand and the availability of generation and transmission resources are uncertain. Therefore, it is necessary to have reserves available in a power system. When capacity becomes scarce, it is difficult to satisfy the reserve requirements. If these requirements are strict, the only possibility is to resort to what can be called ”preventive loadshedding” to satisfy the reserve requirements. This is obviously an expensive solution, but there are no obvious ways of balancing the (societal) cost of preventive load shedding against reduced system security. In this thesis, a model is developed for unit commitment and dispatch with a one-hour time horizon, with the objective of minimizing the sum of the operation and disruption costs, including the expected cost of system collapse. The model is run for the IEEE Reliability Test System. It is shown that under conditions where there is not enough capacity available to satisfy the reserve requirements, large cost savings can be obtained by optimizing the sum of the operation and disruption costs instead of using preventive load-shedding. In the model, it is also possible to directly target reliability indexes like the Loss of Load Probability or Expected Energy not Served. It is shown that increased reliability (in terms of the values of the indexes) can be obtained at a lower cost by targeting the indexes directly instead of resorting to reserve requirements. This is especially the case if flexible load-shedding routines are developed, making it possible to disconnect and reconnect the optimal amounts of load efficiently.
The use of alternatives to fixed reserve requirements as a means to maintain system security does not solve the problem about how to ensure the availability of peaking capacity. However, in a situation with occasional capacity shortages, it gives the System Operator a tool to find the optimal balance between preventive load shedding and system security, which can result in significantly lower disruption costs in such cases. More research and development in this area is necessary to develop methods and tools that are suitable for large power systems.
Ancillary Services
Investment in peaking capacity is insufficient in restructured systems because expected revenues are too low or too uncertain. If generator revenues are increased, the situation improves. One way to obtain this is to create markets for ancillary services. In the thesis, a model is developed for a central-dispatch type of pool. In this model, markets for energy and three types of ancillary services are cleared simultaneously for 24 hours ahead. Market prices are such that volumes and prices are consistent with the market participants. self-dispatch decisions . i.e. given these prices, market participants would have chosen the same production of energy and ancillary services as the outcome of the optimization program. With this model, it is shown that markets for ancillary services increase generator revenues, but this effect is partly offset by lower energy prices. This shows that markets for ancillary services can contribute to improving the situation, but given the remaining uncertainty, this is hardly enough to solve the problem.
Capacity Subscription
Because consumers have preferences for two goods: electricity and reliability, they should ideally have the choice of purchasing the preferred amount of each of these. Traditionally this is not possible . reliability is a public good, produced or obtained by a central authority on behalf of all consumers. Technological progress is presently changing this. Capacity subscription is a method that allows consumers to choose their individual level of reliability, at the same time creating a true market for capacity. It is based on the concept of selfrationing. Consumers anticipate (for example on a seasonal basis) their need for capacity at the instant of system-wide peak demand. Based on this anticipation, they procure their desired level of capacity in a market, where generators offer their available capacity. Demand is limited to subscribed capacity by a fuse-like device that is activated when total demand exceeds total available generation. In this way, the capacity payment only influences the market when demand is close to installed capacity, and does not distort the energy price in other periods. Demand is not limited when there is ample capacity. Demand will never exceed supply, because it can be limited in an acceptable way when this situation occurs. Moreover, both consumers and suppliers can adapt to situations with scarce or ample capacity, and the price of capacity will reflect this situation. There is one problem with the method: as consumers do not reach their subscribed capacity simultaneously, there will be a capacity surplus at the instant the fuse-devices are activated. Two methods to solve this problem are analysed, and it is shown that the problem can be solved optimally by giving consumers who prefer this the opportunity to buy power in excess of their subscription on the spot market.
Policy evaluation
Six alternative policies to assess the peaking power problem are analysed based on the following criteria:
- Static efficiency: the welfare-optimal match of consumption and supply
- Dynamic efficiency: the ability to create incentives for innovation
- Invisibility: with invisible strategies, each market actor pursues his or her own objectives without worrying about anyone else.s
- Robustness: a robust policy is less sensitive to deviations from assumptions
- Timeliness: the ability of a policy to be employed at the right time
- Stakeholder equity: the degree to which all the involved parties are treated equitable
- Corrigibility: the extent to which a policy can be corrected once it is employed
- Acceptability: the degree to which the policy is acceptable to all parties
- Simplicity: ceteris paribus simple strategies are preferable over more complicated strategies
- Cost: the cost of implementing the policy
- System security: the policy.s ability to obtain an acceptable level of system security
The policies are, in short (an example is given in parentheses):
- Capacity obligation: suppliers are obliged to keep sufficient capacity (PJM)
- Fixed capacity payment: a fixed payment is offered for available capacity (Spain)
- Dynamic capacity payment: capacity payment is based on the Loss of Load Probability (England and Wales)
- Energy-only: no explicit payments or obligation (Scandinavia, California)
- Proxy prices: very high administrative prices are used as a proxy to the Value of Lost Load when load shedding is necessary (Australia)
- Capacity subscription: cf. the description above (not implemented)
As could be expected, no single policy performs best on all criteria. The obligation and fixed payment methods do not perform well on market efficiency criteria, as essentially they are not market-based policies. The proxy prices policy is a reasonable policy on most criteria. It is easy, cheap and quick to implement. Because there is little experience with the method so far, there is some uncertainty with respect to if it is effective. One can anticipate that the threat of having to buy power at rationing prices will motivate market participants to avoid coming in a buying position in such cases, and that this will stimulate the adaptation of innovative solutions, especially on the demand side.
The capacity subscription policy looks very promising on the issues of efficiency, robustness and system security. This is especially true for dynamic efficiency: consumers will weigh the cost of capacity against the cost of innovative load control devices, and if the price of capacity is high, a market for such technology will emerge. However, there is a considerable threshold prior to the introduction of capacity subscription, caused by the implementation costs and complexity.
The conclusion on policies is thus that in an early stage after restructuring it may be appropriate to resort to the capacity obligation or payment method if the capacity balance is tight at the time of transition. For the medium-term, or if there is ample capacity initially, it is sensible to introduce proxy market prices to transfer the risk of a capacity deficit to market participants, with due attention being paid to the appropriate price level. Capacity subscription can be a long-term objective.
Li, Jinbo 1961. "A study of reactive power dispatch under restructured power systems /." Thesis, McGill University, 2003. http://digitool.Library.McGill.CA:80/R/?func=dbin-jump-full&object_id=80120.
Full textThe first follows the two-step approach adopted by some electricity markets where first, the generators' real powers are dispatched in the energy market, followed by the dispatching of the generator reactive power support services in the ancillary services market.
Once the generators' real power has been dispatched in the energy market, the generators' reactive power is dispatched according to the minimization of a combination of multiple objectives: network MW loss cost, generator opportunity cost, and generator MW shift cost. The MW loss cost is represented as a function of bus voltage magnitudes and angles as well as the nodal prices in $/MWh found in the first step. Opportunity cost is represented as a function of the generator reactive powers, whose cost parameters are derived in terms of the MW dispatch, the MW nodal prices and the generators' capabilities. The generator shift cost is represented as a function of the generator real powers and the MW shift weighting factor. As these three objectives may conflict, compromises are needed to arrive at an optimum solution.
The second reactive power dispatch approach unifies real and reactive power dispatch by minimizing both MW and MVAr generation costs while enforcing the MW and MVAr/voltage constraints simultaneously. This unified dispatch avoids a disadvantage of the two-step MVAr dispatch, that is, that the MW price signal determined in the energy market may be distorted by the subsequent MVAr dispatch in the ancillary services market.
Several numerical examples under different conditions are presented to examine and compare the effectiveness of these two methods.
Bevrani, Hassan. "Decentralized robust load-frequency control synthesis in restructured power systems." Thesis, Osaka University, 2004. https://eprints.qut.edu.au/14776/1/14776.pdf.
Full textSu, Jifeng. "An analytical assessment of generation asset in the restructured electricity industry." Click to view the E-thesis via HKUTO, 2006. http://sunzi.lib.hku.hk/hkuto/record/B37116381.
Full textBotterud, Audun. "Long Term Planning in Restructured power Systems : Dynamic Modelling of Investments on New Power Generation under Uncertainty." Doctoral thesis, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, 2003. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:no:ntnu:diva-48.
Full textThis thesis describes the development of three decision support models for long-term investment planning in restructured power systems. The model concepts address the changing conditions for the electric power industry, with the introduction of more competitive markets, higher uncertainty and less centralised planning. Under these circumstances there is an emerging need for new planning models, also for analyses of the power system in a long-term perspective. The thesis focuses particularly on how dynamic and stochastic modelling can contribute to the improvement of decision making in a restructured power industry. We argue that the use of such modelling approaches has become more important after the introduction of competitive power markets, due to the participants’ increased exposure to price fluctuations and economic risk. Our models can be applied by individual participants in the power system to evaluate investment projects for new power generation capacity. The models can also serve as a decision support tool on a regulatory level, providing analyses of the long-term performance of the power system under different regulations and market designs.
In Chapter 1, we give a brief introduction to the ongoing development towards restructuring and liberalisation of the electrical power system. A discussion of the operation and organisation of restructured power systems is also provided. In Chapter 2, we look more specifically at different modelling approaches for expansion planning in electrical power systems. We also discuss how the contributions in this thesis compare to previous work in the field of decision support models for long-term planning in both regulated and competitive power systems. In Chapter 3, we develop a power market simulation model based on system dynamics. The advantages and limitations of using descriptive system dynamics models for long-term planning purposes in this context are also discussed. Chapter 4 is devoted to a novel optimisation model which calculates the optimal investment strategy for a profit maximising investor considering investments in new power generation capacity. The model is based on real options theory, which is an alternative to static discounted cash flow evaluations of investments projects under uncertainty. In the model we represent load growth as a stochastic variable. A stochastic dynamic programming algorithm is applied in order to solve the investment problem. Prices and profits are calculated in a separate model, whose parameters can be estimated based on historical data for load, prices and installed capacity in the power system. In Chapter 5, we extend the stochastic dynamic optimisation model from Chapter 4, so that the investor now can choose between two different power generation technologies to invest in. An alternative representation of the power market is also implemented, which makes it possible to use either a profit or a social welfare objective in the optimisation. With this model we can compare the optimal investment decisions, and the dynamics of investments, prices and reliability, which follow from centralised and decentralised decision making.
The main scientific contributions in the thesis lie in the combined use of economic theory for restructured power systems and theory for optimal investments under uncertainty. With an explicit representation of the power market, the dynamic investment models can identify profit maximising investment strategies under different regulations and market designs. The use of physical state variables in the models also facilitates analyses of the long-term consequences for the power system, which result from the optimal decentralised investment decisions. Decision support models for expansion planning in the regulated power industry do not address the aspect of competition and decentralised decision making. At the same time, long-term uncertainties and their impact on optimal investment decisions are rarely represented in planning models for the competitive industry. The stochastic dynamic models in this thesis therefore provide a new framework for long-term analysis of investments and prices in restructured power systems.
Potential applications of the investment models are demonstrated in a number of illustrative examples in the thesis. Through the analyses in these examples we have gained increased insight into the complex dynamics of prices, investments and security of supply in competitive power systems.
Nair, Nirmal-Kumar. "Incorporating voltage security into the planning, operation and monitoring of restructured electric energy markets." Texas A&M University, 2004. http://hdl.handle.net/1969.1/3199.
Full textFelder, Frank Andrew. "Probabilistic risk analysis of restructured electric power systems : implications for reliability analysis and policies." Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2001. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/8257.
Full textIncludes bibliographical references (p. 193-209).
Modem society requires reliable and safe operation of its infrastructure. Policymakers believe that, in many industries, competitive markets and regulatory incentives will result in system performance superior to that under command-and-control regulation. Analytical techniques to evaluate the reliability and safety of complex engineering systems, however, do not explicitly account for responses to market and regulatory incentives. In addition, determining which combination of market and regulatory incentives to use is difficult because policy analysts' understanding of complex systems often depends on uncertain data and limited models that reflect incomplete knowledge. This thesis confronts the problem of evaluating the reliability of a complex engineering system that responds to the behavior of decentralized economic agents. Using the example of restructured and partially deregulated electric power systems, it argues that existing engineering-based reliability tools are insufficient to evaluate the reliability of restructured power systems. This research finds that electricity spot markets are not perfectly reliable, that is, they do not always result in sufficient supply to meet demand. General conclusions regarding the reliability of restructured power systems that some economic analysts suggest should be the basis of reliability policies are either verified or demonstrated to be true only when applied to extremely simple and unrealistic models. New generation unit and transmission component availability models are proposed that incorporate dependent failure modes and capture the behavior of economic agents, neither of which is considered with current adequacy techniques.
(cont.) This thesis proposes the use of a probabilistic risk analysis framework as the foundation for bulk power-system-reliability policy to replace existing policy, which is an ad hoc mixture of deterministic criteria and risk-based requirements. This thesis recommends distinguishing between controlled, involuntary load curtailments and uncontrolled, involuntary load curtailments in power system reliability modeling. The Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE) Reliability Test System is used to illustrate the possible impact that dependent failure modes and the behavior of economic agents have on the reliability of bulk power systems.
by Frank A. Felder.
Ph.D.
Bambenek, Joseph Jerome. "Long-term economically efficient transmission systems in a restructured and deregulated electric power industry." Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1996. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/38816.
Full textSu, Jifeng, and 宿吉鋒. "An analytical assessment of generation asset in the restructured electricity industry." Thesis, The University of Hong Kong (Pokfulam, Hong Kong), 2006. http://hub.hku.hk/bib/B37116381.
Full textBooks on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
Zhang, Xiao-Ping, ed. Restructured Electric Power Systems. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.
Full textBhattacharya, Kankar, Math H. J. Bollen, and Jaap E. Daalder. Operation of Restructured Power Systems. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-1465-7.
Full textBhattacharya, Kankar. Operation of restructured power systems. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2001.
Find full textShahidehpour, M. Maintenance Scheduling in Restructured Power Systems. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2000.
Find full textShahidehpour, M., and M. Marwali. Maintenance Scheduling in Restructured Power Systems. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2000. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-4473-9.
Full textShahidehpour, M. Maintenance scheduling in restructured power systems. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2000.
Find full textHariharan, M. V., S. D. Varwandkar, and Pragati P. Gupta. Modular Load Flow for Restructured Power Systems. Singapore: Springer Singapore, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0497-1.
Full textChow, Joe H., Felix F. Wu, and James Momoh, eds. Applied Mathematics for Restructured Electric Power Systems. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2005. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/b101578.
Full text1951-, Chow J. H., Wu Felix F. 1943-, and Momoh James A. 1950-, eds. Applied mathematics for restructured electric power systems: Optimization, control, and computational systems. New York: Springer, 2005.
Find full textRestructured electric power systems: Analysis of electricity markets with equilibrium models. Hoboken, N.J: John Wiley, 2010.
Find full textBook chapters on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
Song, Y. H., X. Wang, and J. Z. Liu. "Operation of Restructured Power Systems." In Power Systems, 1–12. London: Springer London, 2003. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4471-3735-1_1.
Full textZhang, Xiao-Ping. "Fundamentals of Electric Power Systems." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 1–52. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch1.
Full textCheung, Kwok W., Gary W. Rosenwald, Xing Wang, and David I. Sun. "Restructured Electric Power Systems and Electricity Markets." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 53–97. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch2.
Full textZhang, Xiao-Ping. "Overview of Electricity Market Equilibrium Problems and Market Power Analysis." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 99–137. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch3.
Full textBaldick, Ross. "Computing the Electricity Market Equilibrium: Uses of Market Equilibrium Models." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 139–65. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch4.
Full textYao, Jian, Shmuel S. Oren, and Benjamin F. Hobbs. "Hybrid Bertrand-Cournot Models of Electricity Markets with Multiple Strategic Subnetworks and Common Knowledge Constraints." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 167–92. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch5.
Full textZhang, Xiao-Ping. "Electricity Market Equilibrium with Reactive Power Control." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 193–239. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch6.
Full textAwad, Mohamed Labib, Keith E. Casey, Anna S. Geevarghese, Jeffrey C. Miller, A. Farrokh Rahimi, Anjali Y. Sheffrin, Mingxia Zhang, et al. "Using Market Simulations for Economic Assessment of Transmission Upgrades: Application of the California ISO Approach." In Restructured Electric Power Systems, 241–70. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470608555.ch7.
Full textBhattacharya, Kankar, Math H. J. Bollen, and Jaap E. Daalder. "Power Quality Issues." In Operation of Restructured Power Systems, 253–98. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-1465-7_7.
Full textBhattacharya, Kankar, Math H. J. Bollen, and Jaap E. Daalder. "Power System Economic Operation Overview." In Operation of Restructured Power Systems, 29–72. Boston, MA: Springer US, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-1465-7_2.
Full textConference papers on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
Wu, Felix F., Fenglei Zheng, and Fushuan Wen. "Transmission planning in restructured electric power systems." In 2005 IEEE Russia Power Tech. IEEE, 2005. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ptc.2005.4524801.
Full textCharles Raja, S., P. Venkatesh, and B. V. Manikandan. "Transmission Congestion Management in restructured power systems." In 2011 International Conference on Emerging Trends in Electrical and Computer Technology (ICETECT 2011). IEEE, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/icetect.2011.5760085.
Full textGeetha, T., and K. Shanti Swarup. "Coordinated maintenance scheduling of Gencos and Transcos in restructured power systems." In 2006 IEEE Power India Conference. IEEE, 2006. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/poweri.2006.1632515.
Full textVarwandkar, S. D., and M. V. Hariharan. "Unbundling flows and losses in restructured power systems." In 2013 IEEE Innovative Smart Grid Technologies - Asia (ISGT Asia). IEEE, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/isgt-asia.2013.6698705.
Full textFustar, S. "Role of integration technologies in restructured energy systems." In 2005 IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting. IEEE, 2005. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/pes.2005.1489337.
Full textGumera-Toque, Vida Joan, and Allan C. Nerves. "Optimization of generator Reactive Power Dispatch in restructured power systems." In TENCON 2015 - 2015 IEEE Region 10 Conference. IEEE, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/tencon.2015.7373146.
Full textAlbadi, M. H., and E. F. El-Saadany. "The role of distributed generation in restructured power systems." In 2008 40th North American Power Symposium (NAPS). IEEE, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/naps.2008.5307307.
Full textEsmaeilzadeh, R., M. Amjadi, H. Eskandari, and M. Farrokhifar. "Important Viewpoints of Maintenance Scheduling in Restructured Power Systems." In EUROCON 2007 - The International Conference on "Computer as a Tool". IEEE, 2007. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/eurcon.2007.4400585.
Full textBabaeinejad Sarookolaee, Sogol, Seyyed Hamid Elyas, and Asghar Akbari Foroud. "A reformed capacity subscription market in restructured power systems." In 2011 IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid Technologies - India (ISGT India). IEEE, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/iset-india.2011.6145344.
Full textSaranya, E., and P. L. Somasundaram. "Short run marginal cost calculation in restructured power system." In 2015 International Conference on Advanced Computing and Communication Systems (ICACCS). IEEE, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/icaccs.2015.7324125.
Full textReports on the topic "RESTRUCTURED POWER SYSTEMS"
Independent transmission system operators and their role in maintaining reliability in a restructured electric power industry. Office of Scientific and Technical Information (OSTI), January 1998. http://dx.doi.org/10.2172/567459.
Full text