Academic literature on the topic 'Irving Fisher'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Irving Fisher.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Journal articles on the topic "Irving Fisher"

1

Truuvert, T. "Irving Fisher." History of Economics Review 75, no. 1 (January 2, 2020): 78–80. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10370196.2020.1744877.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Laidler, David. "Irving Fisher." European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27, no. 5 (September 2, 2020): 812–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2020.1816356.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Aldrich, John, and Robert Loring Allen. "Irving Fisher: A Biography." Economic Journal 104, no. 425 (July 1994): 981. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2235008.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Tobin, James. "Irving Fisher (1867-1947)." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64, no. 1 (January 2005): 19–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1536-7150.2005.00347.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Barber, William J. "Irving Fisher of Yale." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64, no. 1 (January 2005): 43–55. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1536-7150.2005.00348.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Fuchs, Victor R. "Health, Government, and Irving Fisher." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64, no. 1 (January 2005): 407–25. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1536-7150.2005.00370.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

SHILLER, ROBERT J. "IRVING FISHER, DEBT DEFLATION, AND CRISES." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 35, no. 2 (May 10, 2013): 179–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1053837213000059.

Full text
Abstract:
This article reconsiders, in the light of the current financial turmoil, Irving Fisher’s 1911 theory of financial crises and his 1933 debt-deflation theory of Great Depressions. Particular attention is given to the role of high debt ratios, high leverage ratios, and changes in the purchasing power of money in Fisher’s analysis, and to Fisher’s compensated dollar plan to stabilize the purchasing power of money. It is argued that indexing the unit of account would accomplish Fisher’s goal of stabilization without the practical difficulties of Fisher’s compensated dollar plan.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

DIEWERT, ERWIN. "IRVING FISHER AND INDEX NUMBER THEORY." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 35, no. 2 (May 10, 2013): 199–232. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1053837213000072.

Full text
Abstract:
There are four main approaches to bilateral index number theory: the fixed basket, stochastic, test, and economic approaches. The paper reviews the contributions of Irving Fisher to these approaches to index number theory, which are still in use today. The paper also reviews Fisher’s contributions to multilateral index number theory. The main themes of the paper are developed in the context of a review of the early history of index number theory: a history that conveys a wealth of information and insight into the making and use of index numbers today.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Humphrey, Thomas M. "Irving Fisher by Robert W. Dimand." History of Political Economy 52, no. 5 (October 1, 2020): 970–73. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-8671940.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Gylfason, Thorvaldur, Helgi Tómasson, and Gylfi Zoega. "Around the world with Irving Fisher." North American Journal of Economics and Finance 36 (April 2016): 232–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2016.01.004.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Dissertations / Theses on the topic "Irving Fisher"

1

Duerig, Oliver. "Fisher-Effekt." St. Gallen, 2006. http://www.biblio.unisg.ch/org/biblio/edoc.nsf/wwwDisplayIdentifier/03604451001/$FILE/03604451001.pdf.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Chan, Milanda. "Searching for Irving Fisher, unit-roots, trend breaks, and the Fisher hypothesis." Thesis, National Library of Canada = Bibliothèque nationale du Canada, 2001. http://www.collectionscanada.ca/obj/s4/f2/dsk3/ftp04/MQ64904.pdf.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Demeulemeester, Samuel. "La proposition 100% monnaie des années 1930 : clarification conceptuelle et analyse théorique." Thesis, Lyon, 2019. http://www.theses.fr/2019LYSEN068.

Full text
Abstract:
Cette thèse étudie la proposition 100% monnaie, telle qu’elle fut formulée aux États-Unis dans les années 1930 par Henry Simons (l’auteur principal du « Plan de Chicago »), Lauchlin Currie et Irving Fisher notamment. L’essence de cette proposition est de divorcer la création de monnaie des prêts de monnaie : les dépôts servant de moyens de paiement seraient soumis à 100% de réserve en monnaie légale, conférant à l’État un monopole de la création monétaire. Cette idée de réforme étant régulièrement sujette à confusion, nous entreprenons de clarifier son concept et d’étudier ses principaux arguments. Au chapitre 1, nous montrons que le 100% monnaie ne saurait être considéré comme un simple avatar des idées de la « Currency School » : contrairement à l’Acte de Peel de 1844, il ne contient en soi aucune règle d’émission, laissant ouvert le débat « règle ou discrétion ». Au chapitre 2, distinguant entre deux grandes approches du 100% monnaie, nous montrons que celui-ci n’implique nullement d’abolir l’intermédiation bancaire basée sur les dépôts d’épargne. Au chapitre 3, nous analysons, à travers les travaux de Fisher, l’objectif principal du 100% monnaie : celui de mettre fin au comportement procyclique du volume de monnaie, causé par le lien de dépendance entre création monétaire et prêts bancaires. Au chapitre 4, nous étudions un autre argument du 100% monnaie : celui de permettre une réduction de la dette publique, en rendant à l’État l’intégralité du seigneuriage – argument souvent critiqué, dont nous montrons qu’il n’est pourtant pas infondé. Alors que le 100% monnaie suscite un regain d’intérêt depuis la crise de 2008, il nous a paru fondamental de clarifier ces questions
This thesis studies the 100% money proposal, such as it was formulated in the United States in the 1930s by Henry Simons (the main author of the “Chicago Plan”), Lauchlin Currie and Irving Fisher in particular. The essence of this proposal is to divorce the creation of money from the lending of money: deposits serving as means of payment would be subjected to 100% reserves in lawful money, awarding the state a monopoly over money creation. Because this reform idea is regularly subject to confusion, we endeavour to clarify its concept and study its main arguments. In chapter 1, we show that the 100% money proposal ought not to be viewed as a mere avatar of the “Currency School” ideas: contrary to Peel’s Act of 1844, it contains no issuing rule by itself, leaving open the debate “rule or discretion”. In chapter 2, distinguishing between two broad approaches to the 100% money proposal, we show that it does not imply abolishing bank intermediation based on savings deposits at all. In chapter 3, we analyse, through Fisher’s works, the main objective of the 100% money proposal: that of putting an end to the pro-cyclical behaviour of the volume of money, caused by the dependency relationship between money creation and bank loans. In chapter 4, we study another argument of the 100% money proposal: that of allowing a reduction of public debt, by returning the totality of seigniorage back to the state—an oft-criticised argument, which, as we show, is not unfounded however. While the 100% money proposal has been arousing renewed interest since the 2008 crisis, we thought it was fundamental to clarify these issues
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Cot, Annie Louise. "L'économie hors d'elle-même : essai sur le néo-utilitarisme." Paris 1, 1988. http://www.theses.fr/1988PA010056.

Full text
Abstract:
En replaçant l'histoire des théories économiques dans le domaine plus large de l'histoire des idées, cette recherche s'attache à repérer et à éclairer le fil d'une continuité intellectuelle et doctrinale du XVIIIe siècles à nos jours : dès lors que le principe d'utilité est posé comme critère suffisant de définition du domaine économique, celui-ci peut prétendre à une extension qui s'élargit à l'ensemble des comportements humains, marchands et non-marchands. Le précurseur est Bentham, relu ici sous cette lumière. L'héritage est ensuite en partie relayé par la tradition autrichienne puis, au début du XXe siècles, par Irving Fisher - dont la théorie économique, aussitôt qu'on la relie avec le credo eugéniste qui était le sien, prend des couleurs inédites - et s'épanouit dans le néo-utilitarisme américain des vingt dernières années;. élaborée par Théodore Schultz et Gary Becker, la théorie du capital humain définit ainsi les bases d'une "approche économique des comportements humains", fondant sa prétention hégémonique sur deux axes : une économie générale du temps humain et, dans une perspective toute benthamienne, une économie générale des interactions sociales, qui prend pour objet les sentiments d'amour, de haine ou d'envie qui peuvent apparaitre entre sujets rationnels. Replacé dans la longue durée, ce projet s'offre aujourd'hui à une analyse critique approfondie
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Vila, Adrien. "Cycles et instabilité chez I. Fisher : l'équilibre à l'épreuve de la monnaie." Thesis, Paris Sciences et Lettres (ComUE), 2018. http://www.theses.fr/2018PSLEH035/document.

Full text
Abstract:
L’objet de la présente thèse porte sur le rôle de la monnaie, en particulier bancaire, dans la détermination du niveau général d’activité chez le fondateur de la théorie quantitative contemporaine, Irving Fisher (1867–1947). Nous y montrons comment évolue sa conception des fluctuations et de l’instabilité en confrontant sa théorie des cycles de crédit (1911) à la déflation par la dette (1932, 1933). Notre objectif est de retracer la manière dont l’essor de la monnaie bancaire à partir de la fin du 19ème siècle, puis des marchés financiers dans l’entre-deux-guerres, sont intégrés dans la pensée de Fisher et, à travers lui, dans la conception libérale de la neutralité monétaire. Nous dégageons ainsi les structures logiques de ses deux analyses, en faisant valoir qu’elles s’appuient sur des mécanismes qualitativement différents, l’un bancaire, l’autre financier, mettant en jeu des variables et des processus de nature distincte. Cependant, une fois cette hétérogénéité mise en avant, il est possible de rapprocher les deux théories de Fisher en soulignant une invariance plus profonde portant sur le caractère déstabilisant de la monnaie. C’est pourquoi les deux grands projets de réformes qu’il défend au cours de sa vie, le dollar-compensé (1911, 1920) puis le 100% Monnaie (1935), sont construits en vue de répondre au même objectif : stabiliser la valeur de la monnaie. Le chapitre 1, introductif, présente les ressorts de la déflation par la dette afin d’en discuter l’articulation à la théorie des cycles de crédit au chapitre 2. Dans celui-ci, nous faisons apparaître que cette analyse de Fisher constitue un cas particulier d’un modèle plus général dans lequel, contrairement à ce qu’il pense alors, la stabilité de l’équilibre n’est pas garantie. Au chapitre 3, nous abordons les solutions qu’il propose pour lutter contre les désordres monétaires. Plus spécifiquement, nous précisons les liens entre sa perception de l’instabilité et les réformes qu’il suggère pour neutraliser l’influence de la monnaie sur les grandeurs économiques réelles. Dans le chapitre 4, nous poursuivons notre étude de la vision de l’instabilité de Fisher en examinant les fondements logiques et historiques de la notion « d’effet Fisher » au sens que lui donne James Tobin (1980). Enfin, le chapitre 5 traite de la réception et de la postérité des idées de Fisher en matière d’analyse de l’instabilité financière. Nous y montrons que la déflation par la dette n’est ni ignorée, ni totalement rejetée par les économistes dans les années 1930 et 1940, puis qu’elle occupe une place importante à partir des années 1970 dans la constitution des programmes de recherche néo-keynésien et post-keynésien
The purpose of this thesis is to examine the role of money, especially of bank deposits,in Irving Fisher’s (1867–1947) analysis of the general level of activity determination, which constitutes nowadays the foundation of the contemporary quantitative theory.We show how his explanation of monetary instability evolves by comparing his credit cycle theory (1911) with the debt-deflation (1932, 1933). Our aim is to highlight the influence of the development of bank currency (from the end of the 19th century) and financial markets (during the interwar period) on Fisher’s economic thought, and through him, on the liberal conception of monetary neutrality. In this way, we draw the logical structures of its two analyses, by pointing out that they are based on qualitatively different mechanisms, one banking, and the other one financial, involving variables and processes of different nature. However, once this heterogeneousness advanced, it is possible to reconcile the two theories of Fisher by underlining a deeper invariance concerning the destabilizing character of money. That is why his two big reforms projects, the compensated-dollar (1911, 1920), and then the 100% Money (1935), are intended to answer at the same purpose: stabilize the value of money.Chapter 1 introduces the dynamic of the debt-deflation to discuss his relation with thecredit cycle theory in the chapter 2. In the latter, we assert that this analysis of Fisher is only a particular case of a more general model in which, contrary to what he thinks at the time, the stability of the equilibrium is not guaranteed. In the chapter 3, we discuss the solutions he proposed to solve the monetary disorders. More precisely, we specify the links between his perception of instability and the reforms he suggests to neutralize the influence of money on the real economic variables. In the chapter 4, we pursue our study of Fisher’s conception of instability by examining the logical and historical foundations of the notion of “Fisher effect” in the meaning given by James Tobin (1980). Finally, the chapter 5 deals with the reception and the posterity of Fisher’s ideas regarding financial instability. We show that the debt-deflation is neither ignored, nor totally rejected by the economists in the 1930s and 1940s, then that it occupies an important place from 1970s in the constitution of the neo-Keynesian and post-Keynesian research program
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Rowles, Thomas (Tom), and n/a. "Development of Concepts of Capital and Income in Financial Reporting in the Nineteenth Century." RMIT University. Accounting and Law, 2007. http://adt.lib.rmit.edu.au/adt/public/adt-VIT20080808.142536.

Full text
Abstract:
The study is concerned with the conception of capital and income in the changing economic circumstances of the late nineteenth century. This issue arises as a matter of interest from the confusing accounting for capital assets then followed, and which has become the subject of a small but significant literature. Methodologically the issue, and the literature it has provoked, provide a 'set' in which an accounting calculation is identified, its context considered and consequences evaluated. It introduces the idea that accounting had macroeconomic implications, and meets Hopwood's (1983) injunction that accounting ought to be considered in the context in which it arises. The study illustrates the significance of a flawed accounting founded on an inadequate definition of capital to adversely affect economic life by reference to the legal debate and litigation in English courts about the definition of profit available for distribution as dividends that occurred at the end of the nineteenth century. The study explores nineteenth century understanding of the concept of capital in economic philosophy on the basis that it would be in that body of philosophic literature that such ideas would have to be examined. The study finds that, for most of the nineteenth century, understanding of the nature of capital and income derived from the works of William Petty and Adam Smith. It held that capital and income were separate states of wealth. This conception of capital continued in the work of David Ricardo, Marx and J. S. Mill, and is evident also in the work of Alfred Marshall. The modern, twentieth century, understanding of capital and income as antithetical states of wealth is identified in the study as deriving from the work of the American economist Irving Fisher in 1896. The contribution of this thesis is to • Establish that the crisis in late nineteenth century financial reporting derived from the prevailing conception of capital and its relationship to income, • note that the conception in legislative requirements determining profit were consistent with that definition, and • identify the origin of the modern, twentieth century understanding of capital and income as antithetical states of wealth. The study provides an in-principle view that nineteenth century capital accounting had the capacity to cause misallocation of resources within an economy.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Lacewell, Jason (Jason Lawrence). "Assessment of Radio-Tagged Grass Carp (Ctenopharnygodon idella) Dispersion, Vegetation, and Temperature Preferences in North Lake Reservoir." Thesis, University of North Texas, 1996. https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc935626/.

Full text
Abstract:
Twenty-nine (Group One, June 8,1995) grass carp (Ctenopharyngodon idella) and five (Group Two, April 18, 1996) grass carp were radio-tagged to monitor movement patterns and habitat preferences on North Lake, a 335 hectare multi-use reservoir located in Irving, Texas. Overall fish mean Average Daily Movement (ADM) rates were 49.2 meters/day (during Half One, 6/8/95-11/30/95) and 5.3 meters/day (during Half Two, 12/14/95-6/6/96). Aquatic macrophtye distribution data were obtained. Radio-tagged grass carp were located in Hydrilla verticillata infested areas increasingly throughout the study, however, percent frequency of Hydrilla along 15 transects did not decrease. Radio-transmitters were equipped with temperature-sensors (10-35 Celsius range). Results indicated that radio-tagged grass carp showed no avoidance of areas of North Lake with elevated water temperatures. Radio-tagged grass carp dispersed quickly from stocking point, then moved into littoral areas infested with Hydrilla. After an initial movement period, most fish remained in a localized area.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Books on the topic "Irving Fisher"

1

Dimand, Robert W. Irving Fisher. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Allen, Robert Loring. Irving Fisher: A biography. Cambridge, Mass: Blackwell Publishers, 1993.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Mitchener, Kris James. Searching for Irving Fisher. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Fuchs, Victor R. Health, government, and Irving Fisher. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1998.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Irving, Fisher. The works of Irving Fisher. London: Pickering & Chatto, 1997.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

McGrattan, Ellen R. The 1929 stock market: Irving Fisher was right. [Minneapolis, Minn.]: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2003.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

McGrattan, Ellen R. The stock market crash of 1929: Irving Fisher was right! Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2001.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Rosenstock, Adolf. Der internationale Zinszusammenhang: Eine theoretische Untersuchung in der Tradition von Irving Fisher. Frankfurt am Main: Knapp, 1988.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Dimand, Robert W. Irving Fisher. Palgrave Macmillan, 2019.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Dimand. Irving Fisher. Routledge, 2006.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Book chapters on the topic "Irving Fisher"

1

Vogt, A. "Irving Fisher." In Statisticians of the Centuries, 268–72. New York, NY: Springer New York, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4613-0179-0_57.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Tobin, James. "Irving Fisher." In Capital Theory, 161–77. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 1990. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20861-6_12.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Dimand, Robert W. "Fisher’s Legacy in Economics." In Irving Fisher, 223–34. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_10.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Dimand, Robert W. "Economic Scientist, Economic and Social Reformer." In Irving Fisher, 1–15. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_1.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Dimand, Robert W. "Indifference Curves and a Hydraulic Model of General Equilibrium." In Irving Fisher, 17–44. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_2.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Dimand, Robert W. "Revitalizing the Quantity Theory of Money: From the Fisher Relation to the Fisher Equation." In Irving Fisher, 45–73. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Dimand, Robert W. "The Fisher Diagram and the Neoclassical Theory of Interest and Capital." In Irving Fisher, 75–112. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_4.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Dimand, Robert W. "Taming the “Dance of the Dollar”: From the Compensated Dollar to 100% Money." In Irving Fisher, 113–34. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_5.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Dimand, Robert W. "Fighting Money Illusion: The Fisher Ideal Index Number." In Irving Fisher, 135–56. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_6.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Dimand, Robert W. "Hubris, Nemesis, and Analysis: “Stock Prices Appear to Have Reached a Permanently High Plateau”." In Irving Fisher, 157–73. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Reports on the topic "Irving Fisher"

1

Mitchener, Kris James, and Marc Weidenmier. Searching for Irving Fisher. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, January 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w15670.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Fuchs, Victor. Health, Government, and Irving Fisher. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, August 1998. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w6710.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Bordo, Michael, and Hugh Rockoff. The Influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman's Monetary Economics. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, August 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w17267.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

McGrattan, Ellen, and Edward Prescott. The Stock Market Crash of 1929: Irving Fisher Was Right! Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, December 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w8622.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Burdekin, Richard C. K., Kris James Mitchener, and Marc Weidenmier. Irving Fisher and Price-Level Targeting in Austria: Was Silver the Answer? Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, June 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w17123.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography