Dissertations / Theses on the topic 'Intellectual property rights'
Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles
Consult the top 50 dissertations / theses for your research on the topic 'Intellectual property rights.'
Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.
You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.
Browse dissertations / theses on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.
Schroeder, Jeffrey S. "Right grantors and right seekers : a theory for understanding the comparative development of intellectual property rights /." view abstract or download file of text, 2001. http://wwwlib.umi.com/cr/uoregon/fullcit?p3004002.
Full textTypescript. Includes vita and abstract. Includes bibliographical references (leaves 260-272). Also available for download via the World Wide Web; free to University of Oregon users.
Myers, Robert A. "Intellectual Property Rights in Japan." MIT Japan Program, 1998. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/7542.
Full textNorain, Ismail. "Intellectual property rights for nanotechnology." Thesis, University of Newcastle upon Tyne, 2012. http://hdl.handle.net/10443/1627.
Full textШуст, Наталія Борисівна. "INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN POLAND." Thesis, НАУ, 2017. http://er.nau.edu.ua/handle/NAU/25315.
Full textBENNATO, ANNA RITA. "Essays on intellectual property rights." Doctoral thesis, Università degli Studi di Roma "Tor Vergata", 2009. http://hdl.handle.net/2108/207738.
Full textHistorically, the issue of intellectual property rights is considered a contentious one because, if the primary reason to ensure a strong patent protection is to provide enough incentives for the private agents to invest their resources in new technologies, on the other hand, such legal protection leads to an increase in the deadweight loss and an inefficient duplication of R&D costs (Scotchmer, 2004). Furthermore, the economic literature that describes the relationship between science and innovation explains that profit-seeking agents without a well defined intellectual property right regime tend to invest less than optimally (Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Helpman, 1993). Thus, in the absence of a legal system that identifies the creator as the exclusive owner of her innovation, anyone is able to reproduce it without extra costs, as innovation exhibits all the peculiarities of a public good. In the last two decades, this matter has become a disputed subject due, in particular, to the new rules introduced by Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights agreement (TRIPs). By uniforming the intellectual property right (IPR) regime at a global level, the TRIPs agreement calls for all WTO members to enforce a minimum standard of protection, without distinguishing the features of each category of goods. These new international rules have risen several political debates, especially for its implications for the pharmaceutical sector and for the social welfare. The international harmonization of the patent system does not yield unequivocal results, since the welfare implications ensuing from a strict enforcement of IPRs are complex. The simple fact that trade flows rise or fall in response of an enforcement of the law of IPRs is not sufficient for drawing conclusions regarding economic welfare. Both static and dynamic effects need to be considered (Deardorff, 1992; Helpman, 1993). With the aim to investigate the economic impact of the international law on IPRs, we employed three different approaches. The first chapter presents a theoretical model of international trade policy, which deals with the optimal patent policy in the presence of a health externality. In the second chapter we adopt a gravity framework to examine empirically the impact of the new IPRs on bilateral flows of knowledge within the pharmaceutical domain. Finally, the third chapter develops a dynamic game between a single innovative firm and a foreign government to provide a welfare analysis that accounts for investment decision in R&D under the regime of international exhaustion.
Bhattacharya, Raja. "Intellectual property rights in outer space." Thesis, McGill University, 2002. http://digitool.Library.McGill.CA:80/R/?func=dbin-jump-full&object_id=78203.
Full textThis thesis deals with IP issues in international perspective (with reference, however, to some leading national IP legislation when and where it is necessary) with special reference to the contemporary legal regime governing outer space. While emphasizing the existing legal regime relating to IPRs in outer space, it explores the possibility of commercial exploitation of IPRs made in space and on ground through the existing international trade system. The increasing importance of cooperation between the World Intellectual Property Organization and World Trade Organization in this regard is also examined, against the back drop of space activities and the outer space legal regime relating to IPRs. (Abstract shortened by UMI.)
Hackett, Petal Jean. "Essays on intellectual property rights policy." Thesis, University of Edinburgh, 2012. http://hdl.handle.net/1842/7934.
Full textBerger, Stefan. "Regulation of intellectual property rights and trade." Doctoral thesis, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, 2010. http://hdl.handle.net/10803/7591.
Full textTrerise, Jonathan. "A justified system of intellectual property rights." Diss., Columbia, Mo. : University of Missouri-Columbia, 2007. http://hdl.handle.net/10355/4788.
Full textThe entire dissertation/thesis text is included in the research.pdf file; the official abstract appears in the short.pdf file (which also appears in the research.pdf); a non-technical general description, or public abstract, appears in the public.pdf file. Title from title screen of research.pdf file (viewed on December 14, 2007) Vita. Includes bibliographical references.
Adegoke, Sope. "Intellectual Property Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa." Scholarship @ Claremont, 2011. http://scholarship.claremont.edu/cmc_theses/289.
Full textAng, Steven. "The moral dimensions of intellectual property rights." Thesis, Queen Mary, University of London, 2011. http://qmro.qmul.ac.uk/xmlui/handle/123456789/9008.
Full textYu, Yudong. "Intellectual property rights and the game industry." Thesis, University of Manchester, 2017. https://www.research.manchester.ac.uk/portal/en/theses/intellectual-property-rights-and-the-game-industry(029fbc50-7a2c-4434-96ec-5abfc42cd341).html.
Full textNie, Jianqiang. "The enforcement of intellectual property rights in China /." London : Cameron May, 2006. http://aleph.unisg.ch/hsgscan/hm00189727.pdf.
Full textBirmingham, Robert B. "Intellectual property rights in software acquired by DoD." Thesis, Monterey, Calif. : Springfield, Va. : Naval Postgraduate School ; Available from National Technical Information Service, 1995. http://handle.dtic.mil/100.2/ADA305992.
Full textBreimelyte, Jurate. "Open Biobanks. Reframing intellectual property rights in biobanking." Doctoral thesis, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, 2018. http://hdl.handle.net/10803/664270.
Full textThis thesis faced the challenge of answering the question if intellectual property rights that are created by the biobanks can be managed more openly to ensure the equitable distribution of knowledge and improvements of the genetic research. The proposal is made to encourage the biobanks to use more broadly open licenses in their copyrighted works, databases and patented inventions. To ease the transfer of knowledge between biobanks and ensure that the genetic research is improving, the reflection to apply open licenses is made. The thesis describes the open sharing model and supports the possibilities to use IP rights in a non-restricting way. The thesis also proposes to use broad informed consent in the biobanks’ activities. Broad informed consent would ensure the right balance between individual rights and biobanks’ need to share collected information, especially, because there are incentives to treat human genetics as a common good. Open consent can be used in the biobank’s activities to ensure that the tissues are not left unutilised. Such form of consent can assure the maximum value of the collected biological tissues. If collected samples are not restricted to the one-time or one-research use, we can expect that other studies perform research on the same samples and the broader scientific information is presented.
Tomkowicz, Robert Jacek. "Crossing the Boundaries: Overlaps of Intellectual Property Rights." Thèse, Université d'Ottawa / University of Ottawa, 2011. http://hdl.handle.net/10393/20149.
Full textZhuang, Yuan. "Essays on international outsourcing and intellectual property rights." Diss., Connect to online resource, 2006. http://gateway.proquest.com/openurl?url_ver=Z39.88-2004&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:dissertation&res_dat=xri:pqdiss&rft_dat=xri:pqdiss:3239441.
Full textHarison, Elad. "Software intellectual property rights : economics and policy analysis /." Maastricht : UPM, Universitaire Pers Maastricht, 2005. http://www.gbv.de/dms/spk/sbb/recht/toc/511861311.pdf.
Full textDutfield, Graham. "The international biotrade, conservation and intellectual property rights." Thesis, University of Oxford, 2001. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.365657.
Full textKenneally, Michael Edward. "Intellectual Property Rights and Institutions: A Pluralist Account." Thesis, Harvard University, 2014. http://dissertations.umi.com/gsas.harvard:11509.
Full textPhilosophy
Torán, Luis. "Intellectual Property Rights, Open Innovation, and Firm's Environment." Thesis, Högskolan i Gävle, Avdelningen för Industriell utveckling, IT och Samhällsbyggnad, 2014. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:hig:diva-17195.
Full textJakobsson, Amanda. "Essays on international trade and intellectual property rights." Doctoral thesis, Handelshögskolan i Stockholm, Institutionen för Nationalekonomi, 2013. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:hhs:diva-2107.
Full textCrowther, Sarah Maureen. "Patenting genes : intellectual property rights in human genomics." Thesis, University of Sussex, 1999. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.313966.
Full textItuarte-Lima, C. B. "Negotiating intellectual property rights in the Upper Amazon." Thesis, University College London (University of London), 2011. http://discovery.ucl.ac.uk/1302064/.
Full textChou, Teyu. "Essays on intellectual property rights and product differentiation." Diss., Virginia Tech, 1996. http://hdl.handle.net/10919/40318.
Full textKiema, Ilkka. "Essays on the economics of intellectual property rights /." [Helsinki] : University of Helsinki, 2008. https://oa.doria.fi/bitstream/handle/10024/42546/essayson.pdf?sequence=1.
Full textBernal, Uribe Juan Felipe. "Innovation, intellectual property rights and international knowledge diffusion." Thesis, Toulouse 1, 2012. http://www.theses.fr/2012TOU10029/document.
Full textThis thesis studies the effects of Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs) on the economy. It makes use of a common framework (i.e. an endogenous growth model with horizontal differentiation) to model IPRs, identify the benefits and the costs associated with their implementation, suggest welfare maximizing levels of IPRs in economies with different compositions of the labor force and, finally, focus on the trade aspects of international policies tending to unify IPRs systems in the world.The first chapter considers a closed economy. We find that the utility maximizing degree of IPRs may or not be the same for skilled and unskilled workers. The equilibrium of the economy depends on its size and composition of the labor force. When skilled workers are scarce relative to unskilled workers, complete enforcement of IPRs benefits skilled workers and harm unskilled workers, which prefer a weaker regime. If the two labor endowments are close enough there is no longer a conflict of interests between the two groups. Both prefer a regime of IPRs that increases with the population size.The second chapter extends the first one to incorporate an additional economy which is larger and technologically more advanced. The R&D sector of the small economy benefits from the knowledge developed abroad. The model predicts convergence in the rate of growth to the one of the technological leader. The positive effect of IPRs comes from the determination of the "technological gap" between the two regions. Complete enforcement of IPRs maximizes utility for skilled labor and, under some parameter configurations, also for unskilled labor.The third chapter allows for international trade. We consider two economies where skilled labor is heterogeneous in productivity within the R&D sector. Trade requires the payment of a fixed cost per variety. There are two regions in the world: the South has weaker IPRs and a less skilled labor than the North. Skilled workers in the R&D sector choose between becoming innovators or imitators. This setup recreates the observable patterns of dominance of the North in innovation, and the South in imitation. Stronger IPRs in the South translate into a reallocation of skilled labor out of imitation and into innovation. Less imitators increase the value of exporting to that region for foreign exporters leading to an increase in world trade
Lau, Pun-wai Christy. "A review on the effectiveness of the policy on protecting intellectual property rights in HKSAR." Click to view the E-thesis via HKUTO, 2006. http://sunzi.lib.hku.hk/hkuto/record/B36439459.
Full textSamartzi, Vasiliki. "Digital rights management and the rights of end-users." Thesis, Queen Mary, University of London, 2013. http://qmro.qmul.ac.uk/xmlui/handle/123456789/8642.
Full textLo, Shih-tse. "Strengthening intellectual property rights evidence from developing countries' patent reforms /." Diss., Restricted to subscribing institutions, 2005. http://proquest.umi.com/pqdweb?did=953999891&sid=1&Fmt=2&clientId=1564&RQT=309&VName=PQD.
Full textNilsson, Ola. "Rights to Software and Databases : From a Swedish Consulting Perspective." Thesis, Jönköping University, JIBS, Commercial Law, 2009. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:hj:diva-10298.
Full textIn recent times companies have been forced to become more and more digitalized in order to spread company information and facilitate communication with clients, con-sumers and their own employees. The knowledge to integrate software and launch the company into the digital world cannot always be found within the company itself. Therefore, companies often resort to employing consulting companies to enable this for them. Because of copyright, the software created does not solely belong to the employing company – the intellectual property rights automatically stay with the con-sulting company that made it.
When the consulting company omits details concerning intellectual property rights in the employment contract, the standard rules in the Swedish Copyright Act and the international directives kick in and give the consulting company the full rights to the programmes that it has created – with a few exceptions. The employing company may only alter the software in order to ensure that it is fully compatible with the al-ready existing programmes it utilises and the operating system it uses. Even reverse engineering is permitted as long as the information gathered is only used for ensuring the compatibility.
Information in databases is protected as it is creatively arranged in systematic or me-thodical way by the one that has made a substantial investment in obtaining, verifying or presenting the information. The substantial investment depends on the one that has taken the risk of investing in the particular database. As databases are rarely made by consulting companies on behalf of a client, and the rules are sufficiently clear as to whom the ownership of the database is, there are few questions concerning data-bases. Because of this, the assumption would be that the current legislation is work-ing properly.
One of the more troubling issues in regards to copyright is that even though reverse engineering is illegal, proving infringement comes down to evidence and what parts that are quantitatively or qualitatively significant in the original programme. Cur-rently, there is no registry of copyrighted works in Sweden and so there is not telling who made the programme first if the work happens to spread. The creators of soft-ware have expressed concern and allegedly lobbied for a new directive giving more protection to the original creators. The culmination of the lobby work was the Soft-ware Patent Directive, which proposed that software should be seen as an invention and therefore eligible for patenting. However, there were many reasons as to why software should not be patented, most notably increased cost and the years of wait-ing for the patent grant, and the directive was rejected. Still, the concerns persisted and no greater protection has been given to the creators of software.
Saumtally, Anissa. "Economic catching-up, Technological progress and Intellectual property rights." Thesis, Bordeaux, 2017. http://www.theses.fr/2017BORD0829/document.
Full textThe objective of this thesis is to propose an answer to the question: Can intellectual property rights policies such as TRIPS be beneficial for developing countries and their catching-up process?To answer this question, we first look at the technological dynamics behind the catching-up process. The first chapter thus provides an empirical and analytical update on the catching-up and falling behind model by Verspagen (1991), which focuses on studying the role of the innovation and imitation dynamics in the catching up process. Mainly, we find that while the innovation dynamic is important for the catching-up process, the imitation dynamic is necessary to ensure that countries build solid capabilities that will enable them to prosper. The efficiency of the imitation dynamics is dependent on policy factors that make up the learning capability of firms and ensure firms succeed assimilating knowledge.The second chapter focuses on understanding the way those technological transfers from developed to developing countries can occur, we focus on studying the mechanisms behind two main channels, that is international trade and FDIs, which represent the main form of North-South interactions studied in the literature. From this chapter we conclude that there is a rich diversity of complex mechanisms.In the third chapter, we thus build an agent-based model (ABM) to represent those North-South interactions and their complexities, with an evolutionary economics approach. The model allows us to study a particular mechanism: transfers through the local labour mobility, a channel seldom discussed in the literature. This allows us to study the impact FDI may have on development and catching-up outcomes. We find that while FDI from developed countries can, under the right conditions, encourage technological transfers and thus catching up, there are potential negative effects on local industries, in particular in countries largely behind.The final chapter proposes an extension of the model that introduces patents, in order to answer the main question. We find that while patents help motivate northern firms to disclose their technology and thus facilitate development, those firms would require a perfect level of enforcement that will be too harsh on local firms, block imitations and also severely hinder the southern firms’ innovative efforts, while generating limited gains for northern firms
Bouvet, Isabelle. "Certain aspects of intellectual property rights in outer space." Thesis, National Library of Canada = Bibliothèque nationale du Canada, 1999. http://www.collectionscanada.ca/obj/s4/f2/dsk3/ftp04/mq64265.pdf.
Full textBriggs, Kristie N. Field Alfred J. "Three essays on intellectual property rights in developing countries." Chapel Hill, N.C. : University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, 2008. http://dc.lib.unc.edu/u?/etd,1573.
Full textTitle from electronic title page (viewed Sep. 16, 2008). "... in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of Economics." Discipline: Economics; Department/School: Economics.
Davis, Tara M. "International intellectual property rights : effectiveness of incentives for enforcement." Virtual Press, 2008. http://liblink.bsu.edu/uhtbin/catkey/1390656.
Full textDepartment of Political Science
Delicostopoulou, A. "Intellectual property rights as a barrier to world trade." Thesis, University of Exeter, 1999. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.286577.
Full textNiwa, Sumiko. "Essays on Intellectual Property Rights Protection and Economic Growth." Kyoto University, 2018. http://hdl.handle.net/2433/232210.
Full textTassano, Velaochaga Hebert Eduardo. "The convergence between competition law and intellectual property rights." Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú, 2015. http://repositorio.pucp.edu.pe/index/handle/123456789/116244.
Full textEl Instituto Nacional de Defensa de la Competencia y de la Protección de la Propiedad Intelectual (IndecopI) tiene entre sus funciones tanto la defensa de la libre competencia como la protección de la propiedad intelectual. Este diseño institucional tiene la ventaja de permitir apreciar con mayor claridad cuáles son los puntos de convergencia entre ambas materias, armonizarlos y conseguir los objetivos que tienen en común. Dentro de esta convergencia, existen temas sensibles, como el otorgamiento de licencias obligatorias, por lo que en el presente trabajo se destaca su carácter de medida excepcional y se plantea que, para considerar su otorgamiento, el Estado debe contar con un procedimiento que brinde confianza y predictibilidad a la ciudadanía y con definiciones claras sobre qué debemos entender por interés público, emergencia y seguridad nacional. Finalmente, se propone que su otorgamiento tenga justificación en un análisis costo beneficio que arroje como resultado que, en efecto, era la opción más adecuada.
Shank, Cara Elizabeth Holland Dorothy C. "Dis-owning knowledge anarchist intervention in intellectual property rights /." Chapel Hill, N.C. : University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, 2009. http://dc.lib.unc.edu/u?/etd,2339.
Full textTitle from electronic title page (viewed Jun. 26, 2009). "... in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts in the Department of Anthropology." Discipline: Anthropology; Department/School: Anthropology.
FALCONE, STEFANO. "Essays on the political economy of intellectual property rights." Doctoral thesis, Università di Siena, 2018. http://hdl.handle.net/11365/1062007.
Full textBortoluzzi, Eleonora <1994>. "Intellectual property rights on software: Patentability of computer programs." Master's Degree Thesis, Università Ca' Foscari Venezia, 2019. http://hdl.handle.net/10579/15956.
Full textKojdheli, Ornela <1993>. "The management of intellectual property rights within network contracts." Master's Degree Thesis, Università Ca' Foscari Venezia, 2019. http://hdl.handle.net/10579/16037.
Full textMarisova, Iana. "Intellectual Property Protection in innovation projects Author:." Thesis, KTH, Fastigheter och byggande, 2012. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:kth:diva-102396.
Full textWright, Sarah. "Harvesting knowledge : the contested terrain of intellectual property rights in the Philippines /." Thesis, Connect to this title online; UW restricted, 2004. http://hdl.handle.net/1773/5650.
Full textVita. The letter c replaces the 'c in a circle' copyright symbol used in the word intellectual on the t.p. Includes bibliographical references (p. 371-392).
Fuhrmann, Thomas. "3D-printing : a new challenge for intellectual property?" Master's thesis, University of Cape Town, 2015. http://hdl.handle.net/11427/15215.
Full textHe, Ying. "The emergence of the Sino-U.S. intellectual property rights regime." Thesis, National Library of Canada = Bibliothèque nationale du Canada, 1998. http://www.collectionscanada.ca/obj/s4/f2/dsk2/tape15/PQDD_0013/MQ31291.pdf.
Full textKarampaxoglou, Thaleia. "Genetically Modified Food and Crops : Risks and Intellectual Property Rights." Thesis, Linköpings universitet, Centrum för tillämpad etik, 2015. http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:liu:diva-119766.
Full textMcCabe, Ariane Ashley. "Strategies for globalization : assembling intellectual property rights for developing countries." Thesis, University of Cambridge, 2010. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.608782.
Full textLeepuengtham, Tosaporn. "The protection of intellectual property rights in outer space activities." Thesis, University of Nottingham, 2015. https://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.685428.
Full textPererva, P. G., A. V. Kosenko, and N. V. Shcherbak. "Compliance-risk of exclusion of intellectual property rights of objects." Thesis, ТОВ "Нілан-ЛТД", 2018. http://repository.kpi.kharkov.ua/handle/KhPI-Press/39485.
Full text