Academic literature on the topic 'Bioeconomics'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Bioeconomics.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Journal articles on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

Fedyna, Svitlana M., Bohdan L. Kjvalov, and Vitaliy M. Ignatenko. "Bioeconomics: the Essence of the Concept, Strategies, Status and Prospects of Development of Entrepreneurial Forms in Ukraine." Mechanism of an Economic Regulation, no. 3 (2019): 16–27. http://dx.doi.org/10.21272/mer.2019.85.02.

Full text
Abstract:
The paper analyzes various approaches to defining the definition of "bioeconomy", clarifying its essence, spheres of influence (field of application), its technological basis (biotechnology). It was determined that the bioeconomy is closely related to the circular economy, the nature of the circular economy, its main differences from the linear economy and the economics of processing have been clarified. It also paid attention to bioeconomic strategies adopted in different countries, identified the main directions of development of bioeconomies of these countries, reviewed the European Union program documents on bioeconomic issues, as well as major funds, international associations, forums operating in the bioeconomic sphere and unite stakeholders. The total volume of bioeconomy in Europe is analyzed (the share of bioeconomy and its percentage in individual sectors of economy is broken down by the share of bioeconomic income for each of the considered sectors and the share of employment in the bioeconomy sector), the main tasks of bioeconomic growth in Europe are determined. The Sustainable Development Goals have been identified and their achievements are related to bioeconomy in one way or another. The bioeconomy development rating based on the Global Biotechnology and Innovation Index, based on performance indicators, intellectual property rights, intensity, enterprise support, education and training, research and development funding, and policy, and policy, Ukraine is ranked in this rating by each indicator. The main economic sectors in Ukraine that use biotechnology are identified. Ukraine's bioeconomic strategy has not yet been formulated, in view of this it has identified the main obstacles to the development of the bioeconomy in Ukraine and directions that need to be developed Key words: bioeconomics, biotechnology, circular economy, “biologization” of the economy, sustainable development.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Penev, N., and Y. Andreev. "SUSTAINABILITY VALUE CHAIN IN BIOECONOMICS." Trakia Journal of Sciences 18, Suppl.1 (2020): 614–18. http://dx.doi.org/10.15547/tjs.2020.s.01.098.

Full text
Abstract:
The concept of bioeconomics covers all sectors of the economy, including agriculture, which supplies renewable resources: plants, animals, microorganisms and their processed products. The goal is a transition to an economy that is independent of fossil fuels and non-renewable resources. Agriculture and forestry, fisheries and aquaculture, as well as the conversion of biotechnological biomass and biological waste, are central to the multilateral new value chain. The processing industry uses renewable resources in various products, in particular, due to the industrial application of biotechnological and microbiological processes, especially in the chemical industry. This also applies to the food, woodworking, paper, construction, leather, and textile industries, as well as parts of the pharmaceutical and energy industries. Thus, the cyclic system and the storage of reusable waste are also included in the bioeconomic system. The aim of our study is to study the degree of development of sustainable value chains in bioeconomics.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Faber, Marcel. "Bioeconomics." Bio/Technology 4, no. 11 (November 1986): 969. http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/nbt1186-969a.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Yaremova, Maryna. "Theoretical conceptualization of the problem of understanding bioeconomics." Scientific Horizons 23, no. 10 (October 28, 2020): 78–87. http://dx.doi.org/10.48077/scihor.23(10).2020.78-87.

Full text
Abstract:
Humankind gives a new meaning to the importance of preserving the environment for future generations, which has intensified the issue of minimizing the consumption of fossil fuels. One of the ways to solve this problem lies in the plane of bioeconomic science, which is intended to promote the idea of production of food and non-food products based on renewable biological resources. It is necessary to substantiate the theoretical conceptualization of bioeconomic content in the historical dimension to provide the possibility to develop an original opinion on the matter. The purpose of the study is to consider the opinions of researchers and the divergence of their opinions on the development of a bioeconomic paradigm. The key tasks are to conduct a retrospective study of the features of scientific thoughts, substantiate the conceptual foundations of an inclusive European bioeconomy, which is described by modern thinking about the terminology of the bioeconomic direction, identify methodological approaches to the interpretation of bioeconomics in the context of sustainable development, develop an original interpretation of the content with a holistic view, where a biotechnological approach predominates, which is viewed through the lens of commercialization of biotechnological innovations and obtaining maximum profit from the sale of biotechnological products. Theoretical and methodological framework of the study includes general and special methods, including historical method (study of the genesis of the concept in chronological order), inductive and deductive methods (systematization and generalization of bioeconomic content), abstract-logical method (development of an original terminology), and graphic method (visualization of the results). The methodological platform for further research is to build models for the development of bioeconomic principles with the outline of mechanisms for their implementation
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Yarbrough, Robert M. "Teaching Bioeconomics." Journal of Bioeconomics 7, no. 1 (January 2005): 1–38. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10818-005-0156-z.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Horan, Richard D. "Wildlife Disease Bioeconomics." International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 5, no. 1 (May 30, 2011): 23–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/101.00000038.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Betin, Oleg, Galina Titova, Dmitry Vasiliev, and Yuriy Efimov. "The role and objectives of bioeconomics in the creation of scientific foundations for the sustainable development of industrial fisheries." Fisheries 2022, no. 5 (October 14, 2022): 47–52. http://dx.doi.org/10.37663/0131-6184-2022-5-47-52.

Full text
Abstract:
The concept of bioeconomics was introduced into the practice of marine use by the UN Conference on Environment and Development in Rio de Janeiro (1992). Since that moment, bioeconomics has been considered as an important direction of the concept of sustainable development. As evidenced by foreign practice, bioeconomics has been developing in the last decade within the framework of the "blue" economy concept. The purpose of this article is to show the importance of bioeconomics in the process of increasing the sustainability of industrial fishing from a historical perspective and to discuss the accumulated scientific baggage on the problem under consideration, which allows us to move to the advanced development of industrial fishing.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Gil, Javier Alfonso. "Man, Institutions and Bioeconomics." Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 14, no. 4 (October 2003): 339–55. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/02601079x03001400402.

Full text
Abstract:
Because bioeconomics is born of the interaction between the biological activity system and its socio-economic activity system, a holistic methodological approach is essential to study the relations between them. However, it must search for increasing levels of reductionism within each discipline to delve into the ultimate nature of each one of the intervening forces, whether economic or biological. This paper explores the economic forces. Through the biological capacity to comprehend, man and by extension, society, accumulates knowledge, the fulcrum from which he is able to dominate over his natural habitat. From this ‘point d’appui’, man builds two basic tools to assist him in achieving the goal of bettering his social condition. On the one hand, he creates institutions that allow him to “live with others” and, on the other, he develops technology that helps him to “live better with others”. Institutions, also referred to as ‘social technology’, tend toward stability over time while technology or ‘material technology’, tends toward instability, which would suggest that, normally, the mechanics of change will originate in material technology and, from there, progress to social technology by way of the political market. The level of progress and development attained depends on the quantity and rate of growth of knowledge applied by a society. In the process, man and his collectivity are forced to adopt new views of their environment through new shared mental models. The concurrence of equipment and political market will ultimately become the prime mover of institutional and economic change as well as change in mentality. Both technologies must keep on an adaptive course of stable evolution since discrepancies arising between them can cause tension between the various social groups. Adequate management of technological shock is essential to avoid extreme situations of social conflict. Herein lie the most important political decisions that a government must confront over the long term.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Kling, David M., James N. Sanchirico, and James E. Wilen. "Bioeconomics of Managed Relocation." Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 3, no. 4 (December 2016): 1023–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/688498.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Pyastolov, Sergei. "BIOECONOMY AS A RESEARCH ENTERPRISE. (ANALYTICAL REVIEW)." Naukovedenie, no. 2 (2021): 83–102. http://dx.doi.org/10.31249/naukoved/2021.02.03.

Full text
Abstract:
The review provides a description of the bioeconomics from the point of view of experts of the committees of the NAS, USA, accompanied by up-to-date information on the state of affairs in this area. The review suggests that, despite differences in national attributes, bioeconomics concept develops from the national science enterprise model to the global research space model.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Dissertations / Theses on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

Ling, Stephen David. "Spatial bioeconomics of subsistence hunting." Thesis, Imperial College London, 2004. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.408938.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Harrison, Mark R. "The bioeconomics of altruism and rivalry /." Digital version accessible at:, 1998. http://wwwlib.umi.com/cr/utexas/main.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Marsden, Allan Dale. "Bioeconomics of Fraser River sockeye salmon fisheries." Thesis, University of British Columbia, 2012. http://hdl.handle.net/2429/43766.

Full text
Abstract:
Sockeye salmon (Oncorhynchus nerka) in the Fraser River are immensely important to British Columbia's culture and economy. Despite centuries of exploitation and decades of intensive study there remain several key uncertainties about the biological system, including those around dramatic four-year cycles of abundance and pre-season projections of how many fish will return in a given year. Recent years have seen declines in the productivity of some stocks as well as broader conservation concerns, leading to closure of some commercial fisheries, and it appears that greater economic benefits may only be obtained if greater conservation risks are incurred. However, the existing literature contains no analysis focused on bioeconomic analysis of trade-offs between economic and conservation objectives in such complex multi-stock, multi-fleet fisheries. This dissertation develops a bioeconomic simulation model to examine these trade-offs. The model is applied to the Fraser River sockeye salmon fishery and parameterized using historical biological, fishery and economic data. In the first set of analyses, the fishery is simulated retrospectively from 1952 through 1998 and the economic outcomes of several management strategies are examined. In the remaining analyses the fishery is simulated 24 years into the future in a prospective analysis, assuming either that the long-term average productivity regime is still valid, or that recently observed changes in productivity are permanent. Given the outcomes of these simulations the trade-offs between economic benefits and conservation risk are described. The retrospective analysis showed that if relatively simple harvest rules had been implemented historically, the fishery could have been 20-200% more profitable, depending on the particular harvest rule applied and the mechanism underlying stock dynamics. The prospective analysis under the long-term average productivity regime found that there is a policy region that would yield significantly greater economic benefits than the currently applied policy while only minimally increasing conservation risk. Under the modified productivity regime, however, conservation risk is uniformly and unavoidably higher, and the trade-offs become more difficult in the sense that relatively more conservation risk must be incurred to obtain greater economic benefit.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Tinch, Robert R. T. "Resilience and management of stochastic renewable resource system." Thesis, University of York, 2001. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.247146.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Greenville, Jared William. "Marine Protected Areas: A Tool for Fisheries Management." Thesis, The University of Sydney, 2007. http://hdl.handle.net/2123/1893.

Full text
Abstract:
The management of fisheries has progressed over the past century in an attempt to solve the problem of open access. A range of controls, both economic and non-economic in nature, have been used to ration the use of marine resources. Unfortunately, many controls have failed to correct open access problems. Whilst a recent development in fishery control, protected areas defined as an area with a fishery free of extractive pressure, have been put forward as an arrangement which may, in conjunction with other controls, be used to overcome the over-exploitation of marine resources. Marine protected areas have been advocated in areas where other forms of fishery management are impractical or unsuccessful (Sumaila 1998). Arguments for protected area use are based around the heterogeneous nature of fisheries, uncertainties in marine populations and as a hedge strategy to reduce risks of over-exploitation (Conrad 1999a). Through the protection of biodiversity, improving the resilience of the ecosystem, protected areas may mitigate the effects of negative shocks (Ludwig et al. 1993 and Bostford et al. 1997). Further, protected areas have been suggested as a means to manage uncertainty and environmental stochasticity (Grafton and Kompas 2005 and Grafton et al. 2005). The protection of biomass and habitat has the potential to improve fishery returns even when stocks are not overly exploited, with the benefits accruing even from small-sized protected areas (Grafton et al. 2005). The use of marine protected areas as a management tool has resulted from a recognition that it is important to preserve biological habitats as well as stocks. From a societal point of view, the use of protected areas should be evaluated in the context of changes in resource rent and improvements in welfare. As fishery resources are often owned by a common group, usually society, management objectives should be to maximise the return from use of the resources, whether for extractive or non-extractive purposes. Given this decision criterion, protected areas can be evaluated in the sense of opportunity costs and benefits. Protected areas will influence the return from fishery resources through changes in access to fishing grounds, and thus harvest, effort and resource rent. Once a protected area is established, the flow of biomass from the protected area to the remaining fishing ground, may increase biomass, influence the effects of uncertainty and stochasticity, thus effecting mean harvests, effort and resource rent may increase. Changes in resource rent are dependent on other controls. Protected areas are a ‘blunt’ policy instrument, in the sense that they are not an instrument to capture resource rent or change the incentives of fishers. Models of marine protected areas in fisheries vary in complexity, however, a few key elements are necessary in analysing the effects of protected area creation. First, multi-species interactions have the potential to be significant in determining the outcome from a protected area; second, effort expended in the fishery must be dynamic, that is, it must be endogenously determined by the model as fishers will respond to changes in rent brought about through the establishment of a protected area; third, institutional structures that govern the expenditure of effort within a fishery will play an important role in the effectiveness of protected areas in increasing the resource rent of a fishery; and fourth, environmental stochasticity and uncertainty need to be included in the analysis. A stochastic and deterministic model of a predator-prey meta-population fishery was developed to analyse the effects of protected area creation within a fishery. Such a model has not previously been used to analyse protected area creation. The model was analytically solved to find the optimal biomass of each species in an individual patch. This allowed for a comparison of protected areas under a range of management controls ranging from those which led to open access fishing to those which led to an optimal steady-state biomass. The model allowed for linkages between sub-populations based on differing density related flows. Further, due to the linkages between species on both environmental and economic grounds, the effect of protected areas on different groups which target different species could be analysed. The benefits from protected area creation were classified into unique and non-unique benefits. Unique benefits were defined as those which solely flow from the use of a protected area as a tool in fisheries management. Two unique benefits were defined: • Improvements in the resilience of the fishery; and • Reductions in environmental stochasticity. The ability of a protected area to both improve the resilience of the fishery, and smooth fluctuations in environmental stochasticity have been shown to lead to increases in mean resource rent. Thus, protected areas were shown to form part of an optimal fisheries management structure. Generally, the resilience benefits were maximised for small-sized protected areas, whereas the reduced environmental stochasticity benefits were maximised for larger protected areas. The dispersal system between the protected area and the fishing ground affected the unique benefits from protected area creation. Sink-source dispersal increased the unique benefits from protected area creation, as stock movements occurred independently of relative population densities. The independent flow improved the ability of the protected area to hasten the return of the fishery to a steady-state and lessened the variation of harvests in the open fishing grounds. However, in the case where the protected area led to large differences in population densities, and if the area formed a sub-population that was linked to the surrounding fishing ground by density-dependent dispersal, the unique benefits are likely to be greater than under sink-source dispersal. The non-unique benefits were defined as those which could be obtained from other control mechanisms. These benefits were non-unique as they could be achieved from more stringent controls on fisher behaviour. The determinants of the non-unique benefit in terms of dispersal were the same as for the unique benefits. However, the economic conditions of the fishery determined the magnitude of the non-unique benefits. For fisheries with sub-optimal biomass, the unique benefits were greater than those with optimal steady-state biomass. The non-unique benefits identified from protected area creation were: • Changes in biomass towards optimal levels; • Changes in species biomass ratios towards optimal levels; and • Changes in effort towards optimal levels. Protected areas in fisheries may be an optimal policy choice to achieve the non-unique benefits of protected area creation. Protected areas, it has been argued, are a relatively low cost management tool, due to the lower monitoring and enforcement costs. Thus, the use of protected areas offer a solution to the problems of over extraction of fishery resources for lower transaction costs, which may erode the non-unique benefits under different policy instruments. If this is the case, then a protected area larger than is required to maximise the unique benefits of protected area creation could form part of an optimal fisheries management strategy. Whether the protected area is larger or smaller than the size that maximises both the unique and non-unique benefits of protected area creation would depend on the level of transaction costs involved in using alternative policy instruments. Protected areas were found to have distributional effects on the fishery due to changes in the species biomass ratio towards the predator species post protected area creation. The creation of a protected area will have distributional effects on the fishing industry if different fisheries target the different species separately. Fishers targeting predator species are likely to gain from the establishment of a protected area, as now the aggregate level of stocks of this species is greater, leading to both greater unique and non-unique benefits. For fisheries that target prey species, the benefits of protected area creation are lessened. The increased predation within protected area boundaries limited the unique benefits of the protected area. The low cost nature of a protected area will influence the portion of the fishery used for this type of control given an optimal policy programme. If protected areas are relatively low cost in comparison with other controls they should be used relatively more intensely. Further, the use of protected areas may hasten the evolution of fisheries away from open access exploitation towards controls which maximise the value of the fishery. With lower transaction costs, the ability to adopt protected areas over other forms of management is greater, and by doing so, the movement towards optimal exploitation will improve the discounted value of the fishery. The analysis presented in this thesis examined the benefits of protected areas to fisheries. The focus of the study was placed on the benefits to flow to a fishery if a protected area was used as a tool for wild-harvest fisheries management. Marine protected areas also have the potential to generate a range of other benefits, such as recreational values, non-use values, and potential improvements in consumer surplus from fish caught within fisheries that use protected areas. These other benefits would need to be considered when determining whether or not a protected area should be created in a fishery.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Pyo, Hee-Dong. "An economic evaluation of coastal wetlands in Korea." Thesis, University of Portsmouth, 2001. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?uin=uk.bl.ethos.343390.

Full text
Abstract:
AN ECONOMIC EVALUATION OF COASTAL \VETLANDS IN KOREA BY IIEE-DONG PYO The thesis undertakes a detailed economic analysis of the coastal wetlands of Korea and applies the double-bounded dichotomous choice model and spike model of the contingent valuation method to systematically evaluate their conservation value. Further analysis including an extension of the original spike model using only singlcbounded data (Kristrom, I ()(n) to modelling double-bounded data for more statistical efficiency to deal with /.ero observations was made. As a result, the estimated willingness-to-pay for conserving the coastal wetlands under the study is S3.9 per month per household, and the annual aggregated conservation value for the entire nation is about 175 million dollars in a conservative scenario. The study then applies a benefit-cost analysis (8C';\) to coastal wetlands around the Youngsan River, an area of dispute between development and preservation in Korea, with a synthesised estimation of the ecosystcm functional values for coastal wetlands and rice paddies developed by reclamation. The results show wetland development would be preferred to its preservation in an optimistic seenano and conventional BC A, yielding NPV of $49million at the discount rate of 8(Yo, IRR of 8.28%, and B/C ratio of 1.03. By contrast, a normal scenario rejects economic feasibility for the development project at the discount rate of 8°/c), yielding a NPV of -$271 million, IRR of 6.5% and B/C ratio of 0.84. With an extended Be A including conservation values for I-year, 5-year and 1 O-year payment, the estimates of IRR are 7.42%, 5.42%, and 4.06%, respectively under the optimistic scenario. Meanwhile, under the nOnllal Scenario the estimates of IRR arc 5.85%, 4.25%, and 3.09%, respectively. In addition, this study includes a discussion of a comprehensiYe review of conjoint analysis and the integrated environmental management of coastal wetlands developing sustainability indicators for coastal lisheries using bio-economic models in Appendix.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Silva, Patrícia Muniz dos Santos. "Corantes naturais das cascas das árvores Stryphnodendron adstringens (Mart.) Coville e Croton urucurana Baill., nativas do Brasil: extração, tingimento, solidez de cor e caracterização do efluente." Universidade de São Paulo, 2018. http://www.teses.usp.br/teses/disponiveis/100/100133/tde-01112018-152734/.

Full text
Abstract:
Esse trabalho objetivou investigar o potencial dos extratos aquosos das cascas de barbatimão (Stryphnodendron adstringens (Mart.) Coville) e sangra dágua (Croton urucurana Baill.) como corante natural têxtil. Os extratos foram caracterizados quanto ao pH, o teor de sólidos totais e a estabilidade no armazenamento. Os extratos foram liofilizados e avaliados por espectroscopia no infravermelho com transformada de Fourier (FTIR), termogravimetria (TG) e calorimetria exploratória diferencial (DSC). Foram realizados experimentos preliminares de tingimento em tecidos multifibra e em diferentes concentrações dos extratos. A partir desses experimentos, foram definidas as variáveis temperatura, tempo e concentração do extrato para o estudo do tingimento por planejamento experimental 2³, em tecidos 100 % algodão e 100 % lã. Os tecidos tingidos em condição otimizada, sem e com mordentes metálicos, foram avaliados quanto à cor, a solidez de cor à luz, à lavagem, à fricção e ao suor. Os efluentes foram coletados e caracterizados quanto ao pH, turbidez, sólidos totais dissolvidos (STD), oxigênio dissolvido, demanda bioquímica de oxigênio (DBO), demanda química de oxigênio (DQO) e teores de ferro e alumínio dissolvidos. Foram conduzidos ensaios bacteriológicos nos extratos aquosos, etanólicos e liofilizados e nos tecidos tingidos. Os resultados das análises por FTIR indicaram a presença de taninos, lignina e celulose nos extratos. Pelo estudo de estabilidade os extratos possuem duração de 42 dias. Nas análises por TG, os extratos obtiveram perda de massa total similares e não geraram alteração na degradação dos tecidos tingidos. Na análise por DSC os extratos obtiveram picos endotérmico e exotérmixo em temperaturas próximas. As melhores condições para o tingimento dos tecidos avaliados é em 98 °C, por 60 min e na concentração de 100 % do extrato. A solidez de cor dos tecidos tingidos variou de baixa a excelente. Os extratos liofilizados apresentaram propriedades antibacterianas. Os efluentes apresentaram valores de STD, DBO, DQO e alumínio e ferro dissolvidos acima dos limites determinados pela legislação nacional. De modo geral, os resultados obtidos indicam que os extratos das cascas de barbatimão e sangra dágua são promissores para serem utilizados como corantes naturais têxteis
This research aimed to investigate the potential of aqueous extracts of barbatimão (Stryphnodendron adstringens (Mart.) Coville) and sangra dágua (Croton urucurana Baill.) bark as natural textile dyes. The extracts were characterized for pH, total solids content and storage stability. The extracts were lyophilized and evaluated by Fourier transform infrared spectroscopy (FTIR), thermogravimetry (TG) and differential scanning calorimetry (DSC). Preliminary dyeing experiments were carried out on multifiber fabrics and at different extracts concentrations. From these experiments, the variables temperature, time and concentration of the extract for the study of dyeing by experimental design 2³ in 100 % cotton and 100 % wool fabrics were defined. Fabrics dyed in optimized condition, using metal mordants and with no mordents, were evaluated by colorimetry, color fastness to light, wash, rubbing and perspiration. The effluents were collected and characterized by pH, turbidity, total dissolved solids (TDS), dissolved oxygen, biochemical oxygen demand (BOD), chemical oxygen demand (COD) and dissolved iron and aluminum contents. Bacteriological tests were conducted on aqueous, ethanolic and lyophilized extracts and on dyed fabrics. The results of the FTIR analysis indicated the presence of tannins, lignin and cellulose in the extracts. By the stability study were found that the extracts have a duration of 42 days. In the TG analyzes, the extracts obtained similar total mass loss and did not generate alteration in the degradation of the dyed fabrics. In the DSC analysis the extracts obtained endothermic and exotherm peaks at near temperatures. The optimized dyeing for the evaluated fabrics is at 98 °C for 60 min and at the concentration of 100 % of the extract. The color fastness of the dyed fabrics ranged from low to excellent. Lyophilized extracts showed antibacterial properties. The wastewater showed values of TDS, BOD, COD and aluminum and iron dissolved above the limits determined by national legislation. In general, the results indicate that barbatimão and sangra dágua extracts are promising for use as natural textile dyes
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Paschoalotte, Leandro Módolo. "A voz neodarwinista sobre os humanos : os novos significados histórico-sociais da ontologia biocientífica /." Universidade Estadual Paulista (UNESP), 2018. http://hdl.handle.net/11449/154106.

Full text
Abstract:
Submitted by Leandro Modolo Paschoalotte (modolole@hotmail.com) on 2018-05-25T21:33:39Z No. of bitstreams: 1 TESE de Doutorado - LMP.pdf: 3219496 bytes, checksum: d0e4a3c01d34a773fbb67a46efb7f8b2 (MD5)
Rejected by Aline Aparecida Matias null (alinematias@fclar.unesp.br), reason: Solicitamos que realize correções na submissão seguindo as orientações abaixo: 1) Falta o número do processo da FAPESP nas folhas em que a bolsa é citada. Confirmar com a FAPESP se é necessário colocar o número do processo também nos agradecimentos. 2) Excluir as folhas em branco que estão entre o sumário e a introdução. Agradecemos a compreensão. on 2018-05-28T12:37:04Z (GMT)
Submitted by Leandro Modolo Paschoalotte (modolole@hotmail.com) on 2018-05-28T12:55:00Z No. of bitstreams: 1 TESE de Doutorado - LMP.pdf: 3219474 bytes, checksum: 3d1561985da9b8d968b144a96442458a (MD5)
Approved for entry into archive by Aline Aparecida Matias null (alinematias@fclar.unesp.br) on 2018-05-28T13:08:38Z (GMT) No. of bitstreams: 1 paschoalotte_lm_dr_arafcl.pdf: 3219474 bytes, checksum: 3d1561985da9b8d968b144a96442458a (MD5)
Made available in DSpace on 2018-05-28T13:08:38Z (GMT). No. of bitstreams: 1 paschoalotte_lm_dr_arafcl.pdf: 3219474 bytes, checksum: 3d1561985da9b8d968b144a96442458a (MD5) Previous issue date: 2018-04-03
Fundação de Amparo à Pesquisa do Estado de São Paulo (FAPESP)
Há pelo menos três décadas a esfera pública vem sendo banhada pela figuração do humano como um ser de natureza igual – nem mais nem menos – a todos os outros seres viventes sob a rubrica da biologia molecular, mais precisamente da genômica. Do DNA como representação da “essência do nosso ser” aos “homens geneticamente criminosos”, vemos inúmeros enunciados serem vocalizados em livros, em reportagens e mídias em geral – especializados ou não – que, como diria Gyorgy Lukács, derivam ontologicamente as características do ser social daquelas constitutivas do ser natural. Desde a inauguração, na década de 1970 com a sociobiologia de Edward Wilson e Richard Dawkins, até os dias de hoje, a figuração do humano baseado na Teoria Sintética da Evolução vem se aperfeiçoando e se propagando nas distintas áreas do saber e da cultura. De forma geral, parte dominante desse pensamento interpreta as qualidades ontológicas dos humanos e, por consequência, suas características como resultados adaptacionista da evolução da nossa espécie com base na fitness genética. Sendo assim, no sentido de contribuir na compreensão do cenário no qual subiu ao palco tal figuração, este trabalho assume a tarefa de capturar alguns de seus significados históricosociais contemporâneos. Por consistir numa figuração com suportes teórico-científicos, a intenção, num primeiro momento, é identificar alguns dos seus fundamentos epistemológicos e ontológicos através da construção do que denominamos de grade de inteligibilidade genômico derivacionista, cuja característica central consiste na “dedução ontológica” das esferas menos complexas do ser em geral as mais complexas. Posteriormente, para levarmos a cabo o nosso objetivo, explicaremos o que consideramos efetivamente novo em seu significado histórico-social mediante as suas manifestações ideológicas – pelas quais práticas políticas e econômicas se operacionalizam. A nossa tese é de que, sob a crise estrutura do capital e seus aportes financeiros, emergiram tanto uma bioeconomia quanto uma biopolítica que imprimiram significados radicalmente novos ao modo com que tal figuração do humano se transmuta de discurso científico ao ideológico.
For at least three decades the public sphere has been bathed by the figuration of the human as a being of an equal nature – no more and no less – to all other living beings under the rubric of molecular biology, more precisely genomics. From DNA as a representation of the “essence of our being” to "genetically criminal men," we see innumerable utterances being spoken of in books, in reports, in advertisements and media in general – specialized or not – which, as Gyorgy Lukacs would say, derive ontologically the characteristics of the social being of those constitutive of the natural being. Since the inauguration in the 1970s with the sociobiology of Edward Wilson and Richard Dawkins, to this day, the human figure based on the Synthetic Theory of Evolution has been improving and spreading in the different areas of knowledge and culture. In general, a dominant part of this thought interprets the ontological qualities of humans and, consequently, their characteristics as an adaptational result of the evolution of our species based on genetic fitness. Thus, in order to contribute to the understanding of the scenario in which such figuration came to the stage, this work assumes the task of capturing some of its contemporary social-historical meanings. In the first place, the intention is to identify some of its epistemological and ontological foundations through the construction of what we call a “reductionist genomic intelligibility grid”, whose central characteristic consists of the "ontological deduction" of the less complex spheres of “being in general” the more complex. Subsequently, to accomplish our goal, we will explain what we consider to be effectively new in its historical-social meaning through its ideological manifestations – by which political and economic practices become operational. Our thesis is that, under the crisis of capital structure and its financial devices, both a bioeconomy and a biopolitics have emerged that have given radically new meanings to the way in which such figuration of the human transmutes from scientific to ideological discourse
2014/27003-2
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Scott, Samuel George. "Incorporating Agroforestry Into Water Quality Trading: Evaluating Economic-Environmental Tradeoffs." Thesis, Virginia Tech, 2019. http://hdl.handle.net/10919/93406.

Full text
Abstract:
Nonpoint source nitrogen runoff from agriculture is a significant contributor to eutrophication in the Chesapeake Bay. The state of Virginia has developed several market and incentive-based water quality credit trading programs to meet federal water quality objectives. In theory, these programs offer a mechanism to achieve environmental goals at least cost. However, in practice these programs face ongoing challenges arising from limited participation by farmers who supply water quality credits and, as a result, often fail to achieve cost efficiency. We build a flexible, accessible, and modular bioeconomic modeling system as a proof-of-concept to evaluate economic-environmental tradeoffs farmers face in an effort to support program participation and achieve environmental goals. We couple a biophysical nitrogen mass-balance model with an agricultural production model and apply the tool to study diverse agroforestry practices. We evaluate the relative efficiency of these practices by empirically estimating a production possibility frontier. We then use our bioeconomic modeling results to define the minimum willingness to accept of farmers, in terms of water quality credit prices, to adopt agroforestry practices that deliver water quality improvements. We extend our model results to estimate water quality credit premiums to compensate risk-averse farmers for undertaking production practices subject to relatively volatile prices in niche fruit markets. We demonstrate that the model generally simulates real-world credit prices, and highlight potential improvements in design for Virginia's trading program. In particular, quality credit trading programs could be more effective and efficient if credits awards reflect heterogeneity in the environmental benefits associated with nuanced land-use alternatives. Our modeling tool offers a framework to support incentive programs that are both economically sound and biophysically grounded.
Master of Science
High levels of nitrogen in the Chesapeake Bay have become an environmental concern for regulatory agencies. A significant portion of nitrogen pollution in the Chesapeake Bay comes from agricultural activities in the Chesapeake Bay watershed. Agricultural nitrogen pollution is not directly regulated at the federal level, so some states have adopted market-based mechanisms to curb emissions. However, some of these programs are seeing less farmer participation than expected. We suggest that part of the low participation rates may be due to program design, and the impact risk plays in farmer decision-making. In an effort to better understand participation in the programs, we develop a method to model these programs’ environmental and economic outcomes. Our method couples a mechanistic model of nitrogen pollution with an agricultural production model and evaluates tradeoffs between economic and environmental values. We find that the modeling method shows promise as a tool for policymakers, researchers, and farmers interested in pollution abatement programs. As a proof-of-concept, we apply the model to a Virginia market-based program and test our low-participation hypotheses. We find that the programs may be more effective if they recognize a greater diversity of farming practices. Our modeling tool offers a framework to support pollution abatement programs that are both economically feasible and environmentally effective.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Marangon, Gabriel Paes. "OTIMIZAÇÃO BIOECONÔMICA DO REGIME DE MANEJO PARA Eucalyptus grandis W. Hill NO ESTADO DO RIO GRANDE DO SUL." Universidade Federal de Santa Maria, 2015. http://repositorio.ufsm.br/handle/1/3780.

Full text
Abstract:
Conselho Nacional de Desenvolvimento Científico e Tecnológico
The goal of this study is to develop Density Management Diagrams for Eucalyptus grandis W. Hill, which will serve as auxiliary models to establish the variation of appropriate density, and the management group, to conduct settlements with the economic evaluation of management employees schemes. To study area were used stands in full density in reduced spacing, located in Rio-grandense Eastern center and Porto Alegre metropolitan in Rio Grande do Su states mesoregions. Of the density models tested, Tang showed good accuracy, with adjusted coefficient of determination of 0,74 and 3,17% coefficient of variation, which served as the base model for determining the population density rates, competition areas, construction of Management Density Diagrams and the size of the average diameter at the time that starts self-thinning for trees planted per hectare density. It was shown that the value of the slope calculated for the model of Tang, was different from that proposed by the author, worth -3/2 of self-thinning law. It was observed that the average diameter size at the time of the start self-thinning occurs with the removal of the population individuals varies considerably with the tree planting density. Preferably, you should lead the development trajectory of the density of trees per hectare below the line of maximum density, where the line of imminent mortality occurs. With reference to the standard diameter of 25 cm was obtained 5 Settlement density index curves describing curves between them proportional exponentially decreasing trends of frequency individuals per hectare with the diameter increment. Management density diagrams with the variables mean diameter, basal area, volume stand density index provided good volumetric estimates per hectare in relation to actual volumes with efficiency of 0,95, indicating good precision. The tested probability distributions, the Weibull function 2 parameters described accurately the frequency of diameters in time, and the re-estimation of its parameters, allowed frequency distributions by diameter class and therefore real development of the stand. The selected trunk shape function was to Hradetzky with determination coefficient of 0,98 and 8.43% coefficient of variation, generating through its integration the estimated volume of the whole stem and parts of it. The Net Present Value of R$ 12.372,35 ha-1 was determined for the management regime with three thinning, at 52,8; 85,4; 121,8 months and last cut at 185,1, higher than the other simulated systems. The Equivalent Annual Value was good and viable economically for all tested systems, the most attractive was the regime where there were two thinnings to 52,8; 85,4 months and last cut at 121,8 months with Equivalent Annual Value of R$1.550,78 ha-1. The internal rate of return was attractive in any of the simulated management regimes, ranging from 6,48% by year in stands without thinning and final cut at 52,8 months at 25,31% by year in stands managed with thinnings at 52,8; 85,4 months and last cut at 121,8 months. The biggest reason benefit on costs was 3.15, obtained in the management regime with two thinning, at 52,8; 85,4 months and last cut at 121,8 confirming the Equivalent Annual Value and Internal rate or return criteria.
O objetivo do presente estudo é elaborar Diagramas de Manejo da Densidade para Eucalyptus grandis W. Hill, que servirão de modelos auxiliares para estabelecer a variação de densidade adequada, e a faixa de manejo, para condução de povoamentos juntamente com a avaliação econômica dos regimes de manejo empregados. Para área de estudo foram utilizados povoamentos em densidade completa em espaçamentos reduzidos, localizados nas mesorregiões Centro Oriental Rio-grandense e Metropolitana de Porto Alegre do Estado do Rio Grande do Sul. Dos modelos de densidade testados, o de Tang apresentou boa precisão, com coeficiente de determinação ajustado de 0,74 e coeficiente de variação de 3,17%, que serviu de modelo base para determinação dos índices de densidade do povoamento, zonas de concorrência, construção dos Diagramas de Manejo da Densidade e a dimensão do diâmetro médio no momento que inicia o autodesbaste para uma densidade de árvores implantadas por hectare. Comprovou-se que o valor do coeficiente angular calculado para o modelo de Tang, foi diferente do proposto por este autor, com valor de -3/2 da lei de autodesbaste. Observou-se que a dimensão de diâmetro médio no momento em que ocorre o início do autodesbaste, com a supressão de indivíduos da população, varia, consideravelmente com a densidade de árvores de plantio. Preferencialmente, deve-se conduzir a trajetória de desenvolvimento da densidade de árvores por hectare logo abaixo a linha de máxima densidade, onde ocorre a linha de iminente mortalidade. Tendo como referência o diâmetro padrão de 25 cm obtiveram-se 5 curvas de Índices de Densidade do Povoamento que descreveram curvas proporcionais entre si com tendências de decréscimo exponencial das frequências de indivíduos por hectare com o incremento diamétrico. Os diagramas de manejo da densidade com as variáveis diâmetro médio, área basal, volume por índice de densidade do povoamento permitiram boas estimativas volumétricas por hectare em relação aos volumes reais com eficiência de 0,95, indicando boa precisão. Das distribuições de probabilidade testadas, a função de Weibull 2 parâmetros descreveu com acurácia a frequência dos diâmetros no tempo, e a reestimativa dos seus parâmetros, permitiu as distribuições de frequência por classe diamétrica e por conseguinte desenvolvimento real do povoamento. A função de forma de tronco selecionada foi a de Hradetzky com coeficiente de determinação ajustado de 0,98 e coeficiente de variação de 8,43%, gerando por meio de sua integração os volume estimados de todo o fuste e de partes dele. O Valor Presente Líquido de R$ 12.372,35 ha-1 foi determinado para o regime de manejo com três desbastes, aos 52,8; 85,4 e 121,8 meses e corte raso aos 185,1 meses, superior aos demais regimes simulados. O Valor Anual Equivalente foi positivo e viável economicamente para todos os regimes testados, o mais atrativo foi o regime onde ocorreram dois desbastes aos 52,8; 85,4 meses e corte raso aos 121,8 meses com Valor Anual Equivalente de R$1.550,78 ha-1. A taxa interna de retorno foi atrativa em qualquer dos regimes de manejo simulados, variando de 6,48 % a.a. em povoamentos sem desbaste e corte raso aos 52,8 meses a 25,31 % a.a. em povoamentos manejados com desbastes aos 52,8; 85,4 meses e corte raso aos 121,8 meses. A maior razão benefício sobre os custos foi de 3,15, obtida no regime de manejo com dois desbastes, aos 52,8; 85,4 meses e corte final aos 121,8 corroborando com os critérios Valor Anual Equivalente e Taxa Interna de Retorno.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Books on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

Introduction to bioeconomics. New Delhi: Global Research Publications, 2011.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Koslowski, Peter, ed. Sociobiology and Bioeconomics. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Anderson, Lee G. Bioeconomics of Fisheries Management. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, 2010.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Strange, John G. Nature and technology: Bioeconomics. Appleton, Wis. (P.O. Box 357, Appleton 54912-0357): Graphic Communications Center, 1985.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Anderson, Lee G. Bioeconomics of fisheries management. Ames, Iowa: Wiley-Blackwell, 2010.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Mathematical bioeconomics: The mathematics of conservation. 3rd ed. Hoboken, N.J: Wiley, 2010.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Clark, Colin Whitcomb. Mathematical bioeconomics: The mathematics of conservation. 3rd ed. Hoboken, N.J: Wiley, 2010.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Pinto, Alberto, and David Zilberman, eds. Modeling, Dynamics, Optimization and Bioeconomics IV. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-78163-7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Pinto, Alberto Adrego, and David Zilberman, eds. Modeling, Dynamics, Optimization and Bioeconomics I. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-04849-9.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Pinto, Alberto A., and David Zilberman, eds. Modeling, Dynamics, Optimization and Bioeconomics III. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-74086-7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Book chapters on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

Clark, Colin W. "Bioeconomics." In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 951–53. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_602.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Clark, Colin W. "Bioeconomics." In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 1–2. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 1987. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_602-1.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Krabbe, Jacob Jan. "Georgescu-Roegen’s “Bioeconomics”." In Historicism and Organicism in Economics: The Evolution of Thought, 115–17. Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands, 1996. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-1689-0_11.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Koslowski, Peter. "Sociobiology, Theory of Evolution, and Bioeconomics Introduction." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 1–4. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_1.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Haken, Hermann. "Synergetics in Sociology and Biology." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 199–218. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_10.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Görtz, Hans-Dieter. "Symbiosis, Mutualism and Cooperation in Biological Evolution." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 219–33. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_11.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Ho, Mae-Wan. "Are Economic Systems Like Organisms?" In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 237–58. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_12.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Saunders, Peter T. "Darwinism and Economic Theory." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 259–78. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_13.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Witt, Ulrich. "Evolutionary Economics and Evolutionary Biology." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 279–98. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_14.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Koslowski, Peter. "The Theory of Evolution as Sociobiology and Bioeconomics A Critique of Its Claim to Totality." In Sociobiology and Bioeconomics, 301–28. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1999. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-03825-3_15.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Conference papers on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

El-Sadek, Alaa, and Jan Feyen. "The Bioeconomics of Nitrate Emissions from Agricultural Land." In World Water and Environmental Resources Congress 2001. Reston, VA: American Society of Civil Engineers, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/40569(2001)6.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Muska, Aina, Andra Zvirbule, and Irina Pilvere. "Factors affecting the development of the Bioeconomy in Latvia." In 22nd International Scientific Conference. “Economic Science for Rural Development 2021”. Latvia University of Life Sciences and Technologies. Faculty of Economics and Social Development, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.22616/esrd.2021.55.002.

Full text
Abstract:
In the European Union, including Latvia, the development of the bioeconomy by exploiting the potential of research, innovation and knowledge transfer is considered to be the basis for economic growth. The research aims to assess the drivers of and barriers to bioeconomic development in Latvia and define actions facilitating the development of the national bioeconomy. The present research employed mostly SWOT analysis in combination with expert judgement. The research concluded that the overall trend in the following strengths of the bioeconomy: Research infrastructure and modern technical equipment for the development of the bioeconomic knowledge base (3S) and Vast regional coverage of and cooperation among leading research institutions in the field of bioeconomics (1S) was negative, as the total impact of the threats exceeded the total impact of the opportunities. However, the overall trend in the strength Extensive initial activities and the knowledge base for bioeconomic research (2S) was positive, as the total impact of the opportunities exceeded the total impact of the threats. The total impact of exogenous factors on the weaknesses in the development of the bioeconomy was positive; therefore, the total impact of exogenous factors tended to weaken the weaknesses. Since the largest positive impacts on endogenous factors were made by the following opportunities: Effective support for independent innovation projects implemented by large companies (3O) and Stimulation of innovation in the small and medium enterprise sector in active synergy with national research priorities and available funding (2IO), it is necessary to increase government and private sector funding for R&D in order to contribute to the development of the bioeconomy in Latvia. The availability of funding should be balanced and predictable in the long term to reduce the impact of the threat Public policies and insufficient and unpredictable funding for research and development hinder the development of bioeconomy industries and steady growth opportunities (2T). To encourage the business sector to invest in R&D, including in the bioeconomy industries, public support and various incentives for entrepreneurs are needed.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Vasilevska, Daina, and Baiba Rivza. "INTERDISCIPLINARITY AS AN IMPORTANT COMPONENT OF EDUCATION IN THE FIELD OF BIOECONOMICS." In 13th International Technology, Education and Development Conference. IATED, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.21125/inted.2019.1617.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Hilgarth, Alexander, Michael Dorin, and Sergio Montenegro. "HONEYCLOUD - Combining Research and Teaching in a Project for the Digitalization of Beekeeping." In Congreso Internacional de Ingeniería de Sistemas. Universidad de Lima, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.26439/ciis2019.5526.

Full text
Abstract:
The HONEYCLOUD project is a research project of the University of Würzburg in the field of bioeconomics. Within the scope of technolog y transfer, tools and methods that were originally developed for aerospace applications are now to be made available for precision agriculture. In particular, the field of precision beekeeping was selected for this purpose. An IT infrastructure to support the honeybees and the work of beekeeping is to be developed. The aim is to ensure that the electronics remain unobtrusive and that the beehive does not beco - me a switch cabinet. This results in an experimental test setup that can be used in the field of teaching Internet-of-Things (IoT) systems. In this way, hardware and software components are created in the project and used directly in teaching.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Goudey, Clifford A. "Wave Basin Tests of a Novel Offshore Macroalgae Farming System." In SNAME 30th American Towing Tank Conference. SNAME, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.5957/attc-2017-0006.

Full text
Abstract:
Macroalgae cultivation in the ocean stands as a promising source of feedstock for biofuels and chemicals. It is particularly attractive because of the efficiency of these marine plants in converting sunlight into biomass and because this type of farming can be done without the risk of displacing land and freshwater from their essential role in feeding the human population. However, there are challenges to achieving this potential due to the limitations of present farming methods. In order to compete economically with land-based biomass production, the bioeconomics of seaweed farming must improve and the areas where it can be practiced must be expanded. Present methods of growing seaweeds are confined to narrow strips along the coasts that are both protected and sufficiently shallow. In order to meaningfully exploit the US Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ), engineered systems must be developed for high-energy locations in deep water and at an unprecedented scale. This paper will present an innovative design for the farming seaweed in the open ocean and will describe a series of tests conducted at Ohmsett - The National Oil Spill Response Research & Renewable Energy Test Facility - in Leonardo, NJ. The facility was used for these tests because the capabilities matched well testing needs and because the facility uses seawater. Actual fronds of kelp were needed for testing in order to correlate their hydrodynamic characteristics with the scaled materials in 1/20th-scale testing of the structure that was the prime focus of the tests. The results on the resistance testing of single and multiple fronds of kelp will be reported as well as those for the model materials. The results of the tests on various structural models both in currents and in currents and waves will be presented. These tests allowed the measurement of system drag and loads internal to the structure. Accelerations were also measured to determine motions and to predict inertial loading. These tests have allowed us to more confidently design prototype systems that have the potential to revolutionize the domestic seaweed-farming sector.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Carlos de Jesus Lopes, José, Bruno gouvêa bastos, Kalil Nascimento Neiva, and Ana Carolina Nogueira Gonçalves. "A EMERGENTE TRANSIÇÃO DA BIOECONOMIA PARA BIOECONOMIA SUSTENTÁVEL: Façamos uma reflexão sobre." In 60º Congresso da SOBER. Natal, Rio Grande do Norte: Even3, 2022. http://dx.doi.org/10.29327/sober2022.485940.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Filatova, Daria V., and Marek Grzywaczewski. "Necessary optimality conditions for fractional bioeconomic systems." In 2008 Conference on Human System Interactions (HSI). IEEE, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/hsi.2008.4581574.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Şonea, Cristinel Gigi, Mirela Stoican, Andra Cristina Şonea, and Alina Iuliana Tăbîrcă. "Bioeconomic Management of Biodiversity of Sericulture Genetic Resources in the Context of Sustainable Development in Romania." In International Conference Innovative Business Management & Global Entrepreneurship. LUMEN Publishing, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.18662/lumproc/ibmage2020/38.

Full text
Abstract:
Today’s society is a reaction to the excesses of a market economy that has not always been properly understood, thus leading to an imbalance of limited natural resources, disturbances in the unraveling of the lives of firms, or even the global economy. However, the eco-economy, under the given conditions, respects the sustainable efficiency of the eco-systems on which it depends. Addressing a fair, balanced attitude can be achieved through a system of implementing methods well-defined strategies, thus using the interdisciplinarity of the concept of development. The present paper aims to argue the need for bioeconomic sericulture management, based on the experience held in the field of sericulture and the untapped potential of this field in Romania. The bioeconomic management of sericulture biodiversity is a new method in the development, growth, and exploitation of silkworms as a pursuit of the sustainable development of agriculture and light industry, the chance of applying sustainable innovation, and relaunching the Romanian agriculture.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

COMAN, Mihaela Denisa, Constantin Aurelian IONESCU, and Mihaela Lixandru (Leasa). "Romanian Economy between Linearity and Circularity. A Bioeconomic Perspective." In 11th LUMEN International Scientific Conference Communicative Action & Transdisciplinarity in the Ethical Society, CATES 2018, 23-24 November 2018, Targoviste, Romania. LUMEN Publishing house, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.18662/lumproc.99.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Carbone, Francesco. "Bioeconomic role of sustainable forest management certification schemes in Italy." In Secondo Congresso Internazionale di Selvicoltura = Second International Congress of Silviculture. Accademia Italiana di Scienze Forestali, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.4129/2cis-fc-ruo.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Reports on the topic "Bioeconomics"

1

none,. Fostering the Bioeconomic Revolution in Biobased Products and Bioenergy: An Environmental Approach. Office of Scientific and Technical Information (OSTI), January 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.2172/1218312.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Research Institute (IFPRI), International Food Policy. Policy analysis for sustainable land management and food security in Ethiopia a bioeconomic model with market imperfections. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute, 2005. http://dx.doi.org/10.2499/0896291456rr140.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Costa, Francisco de Assis, Bruna Stein Ciasca, Ellen Claudine Cardoso Castro, Rogger Mathaus Magalhães Barreiros, Ricardo Folhes, Leonardo Lima Bergamini, Aluízio Solyno Sobrino, et al. Economia da sociobiodiversidade no estado do Pará. Inter-American Development Bank, October 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.18235/0003713.

Full text
Abstract:
O estudo analisa o valor economico e a importância da biodiversidade para a região amazônica, em particular para a economia do estado do Pará e apresenta recomendações para a implementação de políticas públicas voltadas ao desenvolvimento de uma bioeconomia baseada na preservação da floresta nativa e a biodiversidade da região. Os resultados do estudo demonstram que o apoio aos produtos da biodiversidade alinhados à conservação da floresta amazonica beneficia o desenvolvimento socioeconômico dos estados amazônicos e representa uma oportunidade única para um modelo de desenvolvimento sustentável para a floresta amazônica que concilie conservação ambiental e geração de renda para as populações locais.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Fostering regenerative forest bioeconomies. Royal Institute of International Affairs, December 2022. http://dx.doi.org/10.55317/9781784135539.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography