Inhaltsverzeichnis
Auswahl der wissenschaftlichen Literatur zum Thema „Économie du travail – Pérou“
Geben Sie eine Quelle nach APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard und anderen Zitierweisen an
Machen Sie sich mit den Listen der aktuellen Artikel, Bücher, Dissertationen, Berichten und anderer wissenschaftlichen Quellen zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou" bekannt.
Neben jedem Werk im Literaturverzeichnis ist die Option "Zur Bibliographie hinzufügen" verfügbar. Nutzen Sie sie, wird Ihre bibliographische Angabe des gewählten Werkes nach der nötigen Zitierweise (APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver usw.) automatisch gestaltet.
Sie können auch den vollen Text der wissenschaftlichen Publikation im PDF-Format herunterladen und eine Online-Annotation der Arbeit lesen, wenn die relevanten Parameter in den Metadaten verfügbar sind.
Zeitschriftenartikel zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou"
Cavagnoud, Robin. „13. Travail des enfants et économie informelle : le cas du Pérou“. Regards croisés sur l'économie 14, Nr. 1 (2014): 216. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/rce.014.0216.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBazin, Laurent. „Une économie de l’assujettissement“. Anthropologie et Sociétés 34, Nr. 2 (23.02.2011): 83–102. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/045707ar.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBourreau-Dubois, Cécile, und Bruno Deffains. „Économie et droit du travail“. Travail et emploi, Nr. 120 (15.12.2009): 09–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.4000/travailemploi.1631.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBlanchot, Fabien, und Jean-Gustave Padioleau. „Une économie politique du travail journalistique“. Hermès 35, Nr. 1 (2003): 63. http://dx.doi.org/10.4267/2042/9318.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleJacquemet, Nicolas, Olivier L'Haridon und Isabelle Vialle. „Marché du travail, évaluation et économie expérimentale“. Revue française d'économie XXIX, Nr. 1 (2014): 189. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/rfe.141.0189.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleMahy, Benoît, Robert Plasman und François Rycx. „Économie de la demande de travail. Introduction“. Reflets et perspectives de la vie économique XLIV, Nr. 2 (2005): 5. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/rpve.442.0005.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBillette de Villemeur, Barthélémy. „« Grand avantage au service de votre majesté ou intérêts personnnels? » Les conflicts entre le gouvernement du viceroy et l’autorité ecclésiastique (Pérou, 1681- 1689)“. Chronica Nova. Revista de Historia Moderna de la Universidad de Granada, Nr. 47 (05.12.2021): 63–85. http://dx.doi.org/10.30827/cnova.v0i47.18462.
Der volle Inhalt der Quelledu Tertre, Christian. „Économie servicielle et travail : contribution théorique au développement « d'une économie de la coopération »“. Travailler 29, Nr. 1 (2013): 29. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/trav.029.0029.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleZenou, Yves. „Marché du travail et économie urbaine. Essai d'intégration.“ Revue économique 47, Nr. 2 (01.03.1996): 263–88. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/reco.p1996.47n2.0263.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleSabourin, Cécile. „Le symposium « Globalización de la solidaridad »; des échanges d’idées autour de la notion d’économie solidaire“. Dossier : Droit de cité : actions et réseaux féministes 10, Nr. 2 (12.04.2005): 211–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/057945ar.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleDissertationen zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou"
Buller, Vizcarra Carlos. „L' économie du vin à Arequipa : les vallées de Vitor, Majes et Moquegua entre 1770 et 1850“. Paris, EHESS, 2009. http://www.theses.fr/2009EHES0082.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleThe curve showing the output of wine, the main agricultural product in the Vitor, Majes and Moquegua Valleys in c. 1770-1850, is here studied based on the documentation derived from the tithes paid in Arequipa. The curve show the expansion in the output ofwine unti11816, when the sector began its final decline due to the collapse of the commercial networks brought about by the independence of Peru. The dissertation likewise studies the price and commercialisation of wine, similar staples (wheat, maize, potatoes) as well as the local, regional and global historical contexts
Bojorquez, Renan. „La décentralisation dans une économie en voie de développement : le cas du Pérou“. Paris 1, 2009. http://www.theses.fr/2009PA010071.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleRosas, Shady Gerardo David. „Qualité de l'emploi, dynamique sur le marché du travail et inégalité d'opportunités : le cas du Pérou“. Paris 1, 2005. http://www.theses.fr/2005PA010080.
Der volle Inhalt der QuellePasquier, Thomas. „L' économie du contrat de travail“. Paris 10, 2008. http://www.theses.fr/2008PA100100.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleThe Economy’s contract is a promising concept. It enables one to conceive of the contract as more than a set of mutually binding obligations. It is also a global operation driven by finality. The study of this notion regarding employment contract reveals its uniqueness. In regards to French law, the contract’s main purpose is to protect the employee. This protection is mainly set by imperative statutes; foremost, it results from the economy of the employment contract by which risks are to be supported by the employer, as a counterpart of the management power he is granted. Thus the protection that employees benefit from can be construed as the consequence that ensues from the allocation of risks to the employer. Such is the definition of the economy of the employment contract set forth in this study. The notion plays a great role in asserting the existence of an employment contract: what differentiates the independent contractor from the employee is that the former supports the economical risks of his activity, contrary to the latter. The notion also serves to identify the employer’s duties towards its employees: he is contractually bound to ensure their security, as the management power is vested in him. Finally, the notion may account for the evolution of many work-for-other schemes and more precisely, how legislation granted certain employee benefits to independent contractors. In return, the notion seems to have been affected by evolution: within labor law, the employer’s management power seems less accountable for certain work related risks. Consequently, the employee’s protection correlates less to its submission toward the employer
Trako, Iva. „Essays on Development Economics“. Thesis, Paris Sciences et Lettres (ComUE), 2018. http://www.theses.fr/2018PSLEH043/document.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleChapter 1 evaluates the impact of a policy intervention in Peru aimed at improving access to justice and reducing violence against women. In many developing countries, access to justice remains unequal, especially for women. What are the implications of this inequality for gender-based violence, intra-household bargaining, and investment in children? This paper provides evidence from Peru on all-women's justice centers (WJCs), specialized institutions that mostly employ female officers and provide police and legal services to reduce gender-based violence. Examining the gradual rollout of WJCs across districts/ villages, we find that the opening of a center increases reporting of gender-specific crimes by 40% and reduces the incidence of gender-based violence measured by domestic violence, femicides and hospitalizations due to mental health by about 10%. We find, moreover, that a decrease in the exposure of women to violence has intergenerational effects: WJCs substantially increase human capital investments in children, raising enrollment, attendance, and test scores. These results are consistent with a bargaining model in which women's access to justice determines the threat point. Chapter 2 examines the effect of fertility on labor supply decisions of Albanian parents, with particular attention to the intervening role of childcare provided by grandparents in extended families. In order to address the potential endogeneity in the fertility decision, I exploit Albanian parental preference for having sons combined with the sibling’s sex-composition instrument as an exogenous source of variation. Using a repeated cross-section of parents with at least two children, I find a positive and statistically significant effect of fertility on parental labor supply for those parents who are more likely to be younger, less educated or live in extended families. In particular, IV estimates for mothers show that they increase labor supply, especially in terms of hours worked per week and the likelihood of working off-farm. Similarly, father’s likelihood of working off-farm and having a second occupation increase as a consequence of further childbearing. The heterogeneity analysis suggests that this positive effect might be the result of two plausible mechanisms: childcare provided by non-parental adults in extended families and greater financial costs of maintaining more children. Chapter 3 analyzes the effect of forced displacement on adult’s labor market outcomes and children’s schooling in the context of the post-war Kosovo. This chapter uses the 1998-1999 Kosovo war and the following massive displacement of people as a natural experiment in order to estimate the impact of conflict displacement on Kosovars that left and decided to come back relative to those who stayed in the province. I exploit the interaction of the spatial variation in conflict intensity -as measured by casualties and bombings- and distance to the Albanian border as a source of exogenous variation in the displacement status. Results indicate that displaced Kosovar men are less likely to be employed in the agricultural sector and to work on their own account, while displaced Kosovar women are more likely to be inactive. Loss of assets (e.g. land, livestock) in an agrarian skill-based economy and also loss of social networks in an informal labor market might have further decreased the probability to find employment relative to stayers. However, shortly after the return home, the results also indicate that displaced Kosovar men and women are more likely to be working off-farm, especially in the construction and public administration sectors, which indicates a relatively quick recovery. In addition, displaced Kosovar girls are more likely to be enrolled in primary school, but I find no effect on education for boys. The refugee camp experience might have provided better conditions to young Kosovar girls compared to the precarious pre-war “parallel" education system
Pochet, Buttin Christine. „Le fonctionnement réel du marché du travail“. Paris 9, 1986. https://portail.bu.dauphine.fr/fileviewer/index.php?doc=1986PA090012.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleHow does the labor market actually works ? The labor market is nowadays characterized by a high rigidity of wages, which decrease very little even when the supply of labor is high. Thus, this renewed study of the labor market will mainly rely on the analysis of quantity adjustments. First, the concept of labor market is abandonned and the concept of qualification market is ontroduced. Labor is no longer considered as a homogeneous factor, as in the classical theory. This work will demonstrate that qualified labor is exchanged on the labor market i. E labor which is characterized by skills required for a job or mastered by an applicant. This market place will be called the qualification market. Then, this work will analyse how the qualification market actually works. A short-term attitude of business firms will be to take advantage of the flexibility of every employee's qualification (by in-house training) to fit the requirements of production. This phenomenom is particularly obvious at the level of local labor markets. In the long run, technical innovations and the differential development of
Sen, Ananya. „Essais en économie des médias“. Thesis, Toulouse 1, 2016. http://www.theses.fr/2016TOU10074.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleThis thesis consists of three independent and self-contained chapters, all of which have the economics of the media or the internet as the common unifying theme. In Chapter I, we ask whether new technologies change the way political markets work in a democracy. We study the impact of adopting a new technology on campaign contributions received by candidates running for the U.S. Congress. To identify the causal impact of joining Twitter, we com- pare donations just before and just after politicians open an account in regions with high and low levels of Twitter penetration, controlling for politician-month fixed effects. We estimate that opening a Twitter account amounts to an increase of at least 2-3% in donations per campaign. Moreover, this effect holds only for inexperienced politicians who have never been elected to the Congress before. Placebo checks suggest that this impact is not driven by concurrent increase in information about these politicians in newspapers or blogs, TV ads, or campaign expenditures. The gain from opening a Twitter account is stronger for donations coming from new as opposed to repeat donors, for politicians who tweet more informatively, and for politicians from regions with lower newspaper circulation. Overall, our findings suggest that a new communication technology can lower the barriers to entry in political contests by increasing new politicians' opportunities of informing voters and fund-raising. In Chapter II, we ask if clicks received by news stories online, independent of story quality, influence the way editors allocate resources to them, and if so, how? Using a unique online news dataset from a large Indian English daily newspaper, we provide evidence that editors expand coverage of stories which receive more clicks initially. To establish a causal link between clicks and coverage, we use a novel instrumental variables strategy exploiting rainfall and power outages as exogenous shocks to reader access to online news. We find that the newspaper responds asymmetrically to clicks received by hard and soft news stories, giving additional coverage only to popular hard ones providing evidence for hard news crowding out soft news and not vice-versa. Finally, we relate our results to rm strategy and the challenge rms face in handling `big data'. In Chapter III, we examine whether a technology, such as the internet, which increases the set of products available to decision makers, may make the decision makers worse off. We build a model where there is product heterogeneity and decision makers can choose to screen products at a cost. In equilibrium, an increase in the choice set can lower a decision maker's payoff by raising the number of products which, on average, are of lower quality than those which were available earlier. An additional product can impose a negative externality on the decision maker by adversely a effecting the statistical quality of its existing product pool. We discuss applications to the phenomenon of attention congestion through advances in digital technology
Gaspar, Jean-François. „Ethnographie du travail social : une économie des biens symboliques“. Paris, EHESS, 2008. http://www.theses.fr/2008EHES0021.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleHow make the social workers (very mainly women), ''to like", in the exercise of testing professions, but little valued socially and economically, little recognized academically and scientifically? Led in a city of average importance marked by the deindustrialization in one of the former Walloon mineral fields, an ethnographical inquiry allowed to bring to light principles appropriate for the symbolic economy in the universe of the social work. Take seriously "their reasons for being" led to be interested in their practices (often tacit because considered coarse), in their expectations, in their symbolic remunerations under ail their forms. Three poles were identified in the space of the social work. Ln their presentation of themselves as in their practices, the clinical social workers advance their "will" to work "beyond the demand of the user" "to relieve of his suffering". They so appear as first-line agents of what Didier Fassin names "the compassionnel treatment of the social question". The militant social workers advance their humanist or political reading of the world and their "will of social change" that they try to relate to their practices and talk in front of particular social situations of the users. The normative social workers consider their work as "a work as the other one": from their point of view, the respect for rules, laws, standards, hierarchies and contracts is a factor of integration otherwise of insertion
Gonzales, Julia. „Le district industriel de Gamarra-Pérou, le réseau de petites et micro-entreprises : une réponse locale à la globalisation“. Paris 3, 2001. http://www.theses.fr/2001PA030016.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleCordova, Daniel. „Echecs et succès de l'industrialisation : éléments pour une histoire économique comparée, applications aux cas du Pérou et de la Corée du Sud“. Grenoble 2, 1994. http://www.theses.fr/1994GRE21042.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleThis research finds its justification on the divergence of the economic paths followed by east asiatic countries such as south korea and taiwan on one hand, and latin american countries such as brazil and peru on the other hand. The central hypothesis is that these two groups of countries achieved their way to capitalism under two different forms, as far as their actual industrialization is concerned. The aim is to set forth how pertinent such an hypothesis is and to make clear what industrialization and underindustrialization mean. For that purpose, a theoretical work and methodical comparison between peru and korea were drawn. The first part of the work leads to the expression of the main characteristics of the new industiralized and underindustrialized economies, based upon a heterodox theoretical system. The second part of the work is a study of economics in which both forms of the passage to capitalism are analyzed from the point of view ot the constraint linked to international relations
Bücher zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou"
Économie du travail. 2. Aufl. Boucherville, Qué: Morin, 1989.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenBarbin, Adeline. André Gorz: Travail, économie et liberté. Futuroscope: SCÉRÉN-CNDP-CRDP, 2013.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle finden1856-1915, Taylor Frederick Winslow, Vatin François 1957- und Taylor Frederick Winslow 1856-1915, Hrsg. Organisation du travail et économie des entreprises. Paris: Éditions d'Organisation, 1990.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenIrmtraud, Behr, Hrsg. Langue, économie, entreprise: Le travail des mots. Paris: Presses Sorbonne nouvelle, 2007.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenStatistique Canada. Division des comptes nationaux et de l'environnement. Travail non rémunéré des ménages: Mesure et évaluation. Ottawa, Ont: Statistique Canada, 1995.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenL'enfance entre école et travail au Pérou: Enquête sur des adolescents à Lima. Paris: Karthala, 2012.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenTélé-université, Université du Québec, Hrsg. Économie du travail: Les réalités et les approches théoriques. Montréal, Qué: Éditions Saint-Martin, 1990.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenLa fin du travail. Paris: La Découverte, 1997.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenRifkin, Jeremy. La fin du travail. Montréal, Qué: Éditions du Boréal, 1996.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenGérard, Ballot, Hrsg. Les Marchés internes du travail: De la microéconomie à la macroéconomie. Paris: Presses universitaires de France, 1996.
Den vollen Inhalt der Quelle findenBuchteile zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou"
Lauwers, Michel. „Introduction : « travail », monastères et rapports de production“. In Labeur, production et économie monastique dans l’Occident médiéval, 7–27. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1484/m.cem-eb.5.123775.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBain, Emmanuel. „Paul : un modèle pour le travail des moines ? (ive-ixe siècle)“. In Labeur, production et économie monastique dans l’Occident médiéval, 127–57. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1484/m.cem-eb.5.123778.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleLe Briz-Orgeur, Stéphanie. „Étymologie et usages de mots désignant le « travail » en langue d’oïl (xie-xvie siècles)“. In Labeur, production et économie monastique dans l’Occident médiéval, 185–245. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1484/m.cem-eb.5.123780.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleSchroeder, Nicolas. „Servitium et opus. Le « travail » des dépendant·e·s de l’abbaye de Wissembourg (ca 860-870) entre sociologie et anthropologie historiques“. In Labeur, production et économie monastique dans l’Occident médiéval, 297–327. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1484/m.cem-eb.5.123783.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleHenriet, Patrick. „Le monachisme n’est pas un humanisme. Un devoir inédit du jeune Adalbert de Vogüé sur le travail des moines (mai 1949)“. In Labeur, production et économie monastique dans l’Occident médiéval, 569–98. Turnhout, Belgium: Brepols Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1484/m.cem-eb.5.123790.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleSow, Jean-François. „Économie sociale, économie solidaire“. In Dictionnaire pratique du travail social, 131–35. Dunod, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/dunod.rulla.2015.01.0131.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleLorenzi, Jean-Hervé. „Économie et innovation“. In L'Économie, le Travail, l'Entreprise, 25–41. Odile Jacob, 2002. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/oj.unive.2002.07.0025.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleSchmidt am Busch, Hans-Christoph. „Extériorisation et économie.“ In Les théories du travail. Les classiques, 79–102. Presses de l'Université Laval, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/j.ctv1g245kq.7.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleAngulo, Nedda. „Cantines populaires : sécurité alimentaire et exercice de la citoyenneté au Pérou“. In Femmes, économie et développement, 221. ERES, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/eres.gueri.2011.01.0221.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleLemoine, Philippe. „Qu’est-ce que la nouvelle économie ?“ In L'Économie, le Travail, l'Entreprise, 375–90. Odile Jacob, 2002. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/oj.unive.2002.07.0375.
Der volle Inhalt der QuelleBerichte der Organisationen zum Thema "Économie du travail – Pérou"
Poschke, Markus, und David Leung. Le Québec devrait-il augmenter les taxes à la consommation? CIRANO, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.54932/jgvm9888.
Der volle Inhalt der Quelle