Zeitschriftenartikel zum Thema „Economics“

Um die anderen Arten von Veröffentlichungen zu diesem Thema anzuzeigen, folgen Sie diesem Link: Economics.

Geben Sie eine Quelle nach APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard und anderen Zitierweisen an

Wählen Sie eine Art der Quelle aus:

Machen Sie sich mit Top-50 Zeitschriftenartikel für die Forschung zum Thema "Economics" bekannt.

Neben jedem Werk im Literaturverzeichnis ist die Option "Zur Bibliographie hinzufügen" verfügbar. Nutzen Sie sie, wird Ihre bibliographische Angabe des gewählten Werkes nach der nötigen Zitierweise (APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver usw.) automatisch gestaltet.

Sie können auch den vollen Text der wissenschaftlichen Publikation im PDF-Format herunterladen und eine Online-Annotation der Arbeit lesen, wenn die relevanten Parameter in den Metadaten verfügbar sind.

Sehen Sie die Zeitschriftenartikel für verschiedene Spezialgebieten durch und erstellen Sie Ihre Bibliographie auf korrekte Weise.

1

Ickes, Barry W. „Economic Pathology and Comparative Economics: Why Economies Fail to Succeed“. Comparative Economic Studies 47, Nr. 3 (22.08.2005): 503–19. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.ces.8100123.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
2

Konnova, Nina. „Economics of values and philosophy of economics“. Grani 23, Nr. 3 (02.03.2020): 27–37. http://dx.doi.org/10.15421/172022.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
The article is dedicated to the analysis of axiological ideas lying in the foundation of the modern economic science in general and theory of finances in particular. The concept of homo economicus and its origins are considered. Concept of the "homo economicus" is used in the modern philosophic and methodologic literature on methodologic questions of economical science is used in two meanings. The first considers homo economicus only as a technical construct or model created in the form of certain hypotheses and suppositions set taken in their limit form as an idealization. The second takes it as a certain anthropologic type characterized with according values and behavior. It was demonstrated that the concept of homo economicus has a long before-history consisting in gradual break-up between economical theory and ethics. The homo economicus is a person who build his behavior through calculation of his profit. The latter is a form of his self-discipline that forms a new system of norms free from moral and other similar things. The new system of norms suppose no stable tenets and axioms as it takes place in ethics but remains rational and is based on probabilities calculations. The evolution of economical science is regarded as well as its division into political philosophy and proper economic theory in the end of the XIX century, the role of the growth principle, the growth in spite of anything that stood to the first place in the time of the Great Depression and goes on occupying this place till now. It is demonstrated that the essence of money consists in being a symbol and sign of debt obligations, that the capital is representation of their accumulated form and moving power that makes market economics to move. It is shown also that namely the ideas of capital as well as labour compound axiological foundation of modern economical ideas. The homo economicus or economical man, that means individualistic and egotistic psychotype oriented onto profit and satisfaction of his desires, becomes conceptual ideal.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
3

Kurz, Heinz D. „Which Economics? Which Economies?“ Homo Oeconomicus 33, Nr. 4 (30.09.2016): 297–310. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s41412-016-0030-3.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
4

Worswick, David, und Alec Cairncross. „Economics and Economic Policy.“ Economic Journal 97, Nr. 387 (September 1987): 761. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2232943.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
5

Baines, Dudley. „Economics and economic policy“. International Affairs 63, Nr. 4 (1987): 685. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2619711.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
6

Jones, Marcus D., und Charles H. Rowell. „Economics and Economic Conditions“. Callaloo 27, Nr. 1 (2004): 33–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/cal.2004.0011.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
7

SZMRECSÁNYI, TAMÁS. „História econômica, teoria econômica e economia aplicada“. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 12, Nr. 3 (1992): 448–55. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/0101-31571992-0574.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
RESUMO Esta nota trata da importância da história econômica na formação de um economista. Com a ajuda de grandes profissionais do passado, notadamente Schumpeter e Kula, o artigo mostra que, sem uma grande compreensão do passado, não pode haver análise consistente dos fatores econômicos presentes (e futuros).
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
8

Dimand, Robert W., und Robert H. Koehn. „Jane Jacobs, Economies and Economics“. Journal of Economic Asymmetries 7, Nr. 1 (Juni 2010): 175–85. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeca.2010.01.009.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
9

Griffith, Winston H. „Neoliberal Economics and Caribbean Economies“. Journal of Economic Issues 44, Nr. 2 (Juni 2010): 505–12. http://dx.doi.org/10.2753/jei0021-3624440223.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
10

Ho, Samuel P. S. „Economics, Economic Bureaucracy, and Taiwan's Economic Development“. Pacific Affairs 60, Nr. 2 (1987): 226. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2758133.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
11

Vukonić, Boris. „ECONOMIC THEORY AND TOURISM ECONOMICS“. Acta turistica 30, SI (November 2018): 17–63. http://dx.doi.org/10.22598/at/2018.30.si.17.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
12

Yu, Yi-Jang. „Economic Natural Laws and Economics“. Modern Economy 06, Nr. 01 (2015): 12–20. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/me.2015.61002.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
13

Bucovetsky, Sam, Torsten Persson und Guido Tabellini. „Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy“. Southern Economic Journal 68, Nr. 3 (Januar 2002): 738. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1061733.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
14

Samuelson, Larry. „Economic Theory and Experimental Economics“. Journal of Economic Literature 43, Nr. 1 (01.02.2005): 65–107. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/0022051053737816.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
This paper explores the questions of how economic theory can be used to design and interpret experiments and how experimental results can be used to construct and interpret economic theories. The relationship between economic theory and experiments is modeled and illustrated with examples from both theoretical and experimental work. The emphasis is on combing theory and experiment to the benefit of both.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
15

Woodroffe, Neil P. „Geographical economics or economic geography?“ Journal of Geography in Higher Education 18, Nr. 1 (Januar 1994): 98–105. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03098269408709243.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
16

Knežević, Vladimir, Dragan Ivković und Aleksandra Penjišević. „Institutional economics and economic development“. Ekonomika 66, Nr. 3 (2020): 81–94. http://dx.doi.org/10.5937/ekonomika2003081k.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
This research deals with the relationship between economic quality of institutions and economic development. For obtaining the value quantification of institutional quality, we measured rankings of 138 most important national economies based on three pillars of competitiveness, and we used Gross national product per capita to measure development. We applied Spearman`s rank correlation coefficient based on these two parameters for measuring the relationship between ranking of national economies. There is no doubt that a strong direct relationship was recognised. The value of the result lies in the identification of institutional economics as the major cause for different development levels of certain countries. This implies that in case of value measurement of our country, also the most efficient tool would be to put focus on increase of institutional quality.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
17

Duflo, Esther. „American Economic Journal: Applied Economics“. American Economic Review 99, Nr. 2 (01.04.2009): 676–78. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.2.676.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
18

Prasad, Biman C. „Institutional economics and economic development“. International Journal of Social Economics 30, Nr. 6 (Juni 2003): 741–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/03068290310474120.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
19

Bjorvatn, Kjetil. „Islamic Economics and Economic Development“. Forum for Development Studies 25, Nr. 2 (Januar 1998): 229–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/08039410.1998.9666084.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
20

Barker, Drucilla K. „Economics, economic anthropology, and debt“. Journal of Cultural Economy 9, Nr. 6 (20.04.2016): 611–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/17530350.2016.1172020.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
21

Strange, Susan. „Review: International Economics: Economic Statecraft“. International Journal: Canada's Journal of Global Policy Analysis 41, Nr. 4 (Dezember 1986): 896–98. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002070208604100415.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
22

REISMAN, DAVID A. „Economic sociology and institutional economics“. Journal of Institutional Economics 3, Nr. 1 (April 2007): 91–112. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1744137406000579.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
Abstract:Economic sociology was a core concern of early political economists like Smith, Marx, Pareto, and Marshall. The new economic sociology has sought to revive the neglected subdiscipline using the construct of interpersonal networks. Richard Swedberg has assembled 42 substantial papers in this collection. This article, reviewing his selection, proceeds in three stages. First, it provides a general framework for the debate. Second, it discusses the papers specifically linked to networks. Third, it analyses the contributions that go beyond the concept of social processes as personal relationships.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
23

Christy, Ralph D. „“Economic Correctness” and Agricultural Economics“. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 25, Nr. 1 (Juli 1993): 1–13. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1074070800018551.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
AbstractThis address is directed toward applied economists as they provide information to private and public decision makers. Central to this discussion is the role of markets as institutions in achieving society's desired ends. Current “economic correctness”–the view that unfettered markets are superior in achieving efficiency, growth, and welfare-has attempted to return a larger role to the private sector, but the relative roles of market-oriented versus government-oriented solutions to problems are often not well appraised. Views presented herein calls for agricultural economists to move simultaneously toward an understanding of the strategic behavior of firms in imperfectly competitive markets and toward an adoption of policy analysis consistent with a socially complex and globally integrated economy.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
24

Watts, Mike, und Ross Guest. „Experimental Economics and Economic Education“. International Review of Economics Education 9, Nr. 2 (2010): 6–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s1477-3880(15)30045-1.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
25

Güth, Werner, Karl-Erik Wärneryd und Stephen E. G. Lea. „Economic psychology and experimental economics“. Journal of Economic Psychology 13, Nr. 2 (Juni 1992): 199–201. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-4870(92)90029-7.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
26

Victor, Peter A. „Ecological economics and economic growtha“. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1185, Nr. 1 (Januar 2010): 237–45. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1749-6632.2009.05284.x.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
27

Wanner, Eric. „Economic Psychology or Psychological Economics?“ Contemporary Psychology: A Journal of Reviews 34, Nr. 11 (November 1989): 990–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/030721.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
28

O'Leary, James P. „Economic warfare and strategic economics“. Comparative Strategy 5, Nr. 2 (Januar 1985): 179–206. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01495938508402688.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
29

Boschma, Ron A., und Jan G. Lambooy. „Evolutionary economics and economic geography“. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 9, Nr. 4 (07.12.1999): 411–29. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s001910050089.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
30

Komarovskaia, N. V. „THE EVOLUTION OF HOMO ECONOMICUS“. MGIMO Review of International Relations, Nr. 1(46) (28.02.2016): 129–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.24833/2071-8160-2016-1-46-129-142.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
The article provides a review of the ways in which interdisciplinary research in modern economic thought gives a more realistic understanding of human behavior and economic decision making. On the one hand, economic imperialism drove wider application of economics methods across social sciences and brought about new interdisciplinary fields, such as law and economics, economic sociology, public choice theory, etc. On the other hand, the origin of behavioral economics, experimental economics, and neuroeconomics bridging psychology, neurobiology, and economics influences the change in the methodology used by the economics itself and fuels transformation of the model of rational economic behavior 'homo economicus', one of the central assumptions of the neoclassical economics. George Akerlof and Robert Shiller's animal spirits, prospect theory of Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, research by Amartya Sen, Daniel McFadden, Vernon Smith, and other economists focusing on decision making either significantly limit, or supplement the homo economicus concept providing a deeper insight into the nature of human rationality. Behavioral economics has already become so strong as a separate discipline that it can be classified into two streams - Classical and Modern, and its main principles should be incorporated into a basic course of traditional economics. The achievements of behavioral economics yield higher quality of economic research and forecasting. Interdisciplinary approach to the human behavior studies and transformation of homo economicus offer new tools for the development policy making.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
31

Morgan, Mary S. „Technocratic Economics“. History of Political Economy 52, S1 (01.12.2020): 294–304. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-8718067.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
Twentieth-century economics has been characterized as developing an engineering mentality, but this history suggests the importance of distinguishing between a design approach and a problem-solving approach. The former is to be found in economists tasked with reconstructing broken economies (from war or depression) as well as creating “modern” economies in postwar developmental states. The latter is marked by the development of engineering-type tools to solve particular economic problems. While the former mode came into its own in mid-century, and lost confidence in later years, the latter grew up from the early part of the century and maintains its kudos. Accounting for this history depends in part on multiple and sometimes complex intersections between economists and other disciplines. But at least as important were the economic and political events of the century, which molded economists’ experiences and fostered their ambitions to make their technocratic economics usable in the world. This involved more than fashioning “tools” to solve specific problems, more than making “cameras” to describe and analyze the world, but even creating “engines” to help design and run economies.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
32

Backhouse, Roger E. „History of economics, economics and economic history in Britain, 1824 – 2000“. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 11, Nr. 1 (März 2004): 107–27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/0967256032000171524.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
33

Kashian, Abdol Mohammad. „The Criteria for Economic Policymaking: From Conventional Economics to Islamic Economics“. Biquarterly Journal of Economic Research 10, Nr. 18 (01.09.2017): 107–39. http://dx.doi.org/10.29252/jep.10.18.107.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
34

Lee, Jae-Yool. „Early Development Economics and External Economies“. JOURNAL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES 28, Nr. 1 (30.06.2009): 225. http://dx.doi.org/10.18284/jss.2009.06.28.1.225.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
35

Chakravarty, Sukhamoy. „Marxist economics and contemporary developing economies“. Cambridge Journal of Economics 11, Nr. 1 (März 1987): 3–22. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035014.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
36

Thompson, Grahame F. „Where goes economics and the economies?“ Economy and Society 26, Nr. 4 (November 1997): 599–615. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03085149700000031.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
37

Mirrlees, J. „WELFARE ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIES OF SCALE“. Japanese Economic Review 46, Nr. 1 (März 1995): 38–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-5876.1995.tb00004.x.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
38

Lin, Justin Yifu. „New structural economics: the third generation of development economics“. Asian Education and Development Studies 9, Nr. 3 (02.12.2019): 279–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/aeds-02-2019-0039.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
Purpose Development economics is a new sub-discipline in modern economics. The first generation of development economics is structuralism. The second generation of development economics is neoliberalism. Most developing countries followed the above two generations of development economics and failed to achieve industrialization and modernization. The purpose of this paper is to introduce the third generation of development economics, called new structural economics, which advises governments in developing countries to play a facilitating role in the development of industries in a market economy according to the country’s comparative advantages. The paper also discusses how the government may use industrial policies to play this facilitating role and some new theoretical insights from new structural economics. Design/methodology/approach The paper draws on the experiences of success and failure in developing countries to generate new understanding about the nature and causes of economic development in developing countries. Findings The structuralism failed because it ignored the endogeneity of economic structure in a country. The neoliberalism failed because it neglected the endogeneity of distortions in the transition economies. Originality/value The paper proposes new policy and theoretical framework for developing countries.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
39

JAMKA, BEATA. „RELATIONS AS A BASIC RESOURCE OF „NEW ECONOMIES” – CHALLENGE FOR MANAGEMENT“. sj-economics scientific journal 28, Nr. 1 (30.03.2018): 38–53. http://dx.doi.org/10.58246/sjeconomics.v28i1.139.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
The economic crisis of the end of the first decade of 21st century called one’s attention to aims and values of economy, in particular to the deepening depreciation of the human ones. “New economies” being the matter under discussion in the article (sharing economy, the thank you economy, and the economics of “free stuff”) emerge from observations of current economical processes, and take attempt to get the meaning of them in the changed/changing under technological influence new reality, in which the basic role is played by intangible resources, especially by human relations. The aim of the article is to visualize the growing importance of relations as foundations and leading asset of contemporary economics. The argument is based on critical analysis of subject literature of economics, psychology and sociology, and research reports. Despite their evident lacks and not specified ground terms, “new economies” lead a core statement of the need for the aims of economy paradigm change, to make them fit better to the changed/changing socio-economical practice.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
40

Maduforo, A. N., G. T. O. Otitoju, B. O. Mbah und C. E. Okoro. „Linking Nutrition Economics with Economic Principles“. Pakistan Journal of Nutrition 18, Nr. 9 (15.08.2019): 810–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.3923/pjn.2019.810.816.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
41

Doležalová, Antonie. „Economic History or History of Economics?“ Politická ekonomie 60, Nr. 3 (01.06.2012): 419–22. http://dx.doi.org/10.18267/j.polek.853.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
42

Tkachenko, A. A. „Economics of population versus economic demography“. Statistics and Economics, Nr. 5 (01.01.2017): 94–104. http://dx.doi.org/10.21686/2500-3925-2017-5-94-104.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
43

Lugachev, Mihail. „Information Revolutions, Economics and Economic Education“. Moscow University Economics Bulletin 2017, Nr. 4 (31.08.2017): 142–60. http://dx.doi.org/10.38050/01300105201747.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
The concept of permanent revolution was formulated in the XIX century became a subject of constant debate in humanities circle. In contrast-scientific and technological revolutions are natural components at all steps of human development. Their permanence is commonly recognized imperative, followed by numerous confirmations with a convincing inevitability. Information and industrial revolutions taking place now in the world are such evidences. Experts declare today the fourth industrial revolution. Peter Drucker fairly predicted the fourth information revolution. It is interesting that the most important trait of both revolutions is the artificial intelligence which functions in the sphere of Big Data and Internet of Things. The application field (not the only) is the economy-its structure and content. Experts state the emergence of information capitalism and the information economy — innovations obtaining special and revolutional traits. The article is devoted to analysis of main components of the innovations and offers the ways how they should be reflected in the curriculum for modern economists and managers.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
44

Sutinen, Jon G. „Enforcement economics in Exclusive Economic Zones“. GeoJournal 16, Nr. 3 (April 1988): 273–81. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf00270257.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
45

Vranceanu, Radu, und Jérôme Barthélemy. „Knowledge in Economics and Economic Reform“. Revue économique 63, Nr. 6 (2012): 1193. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/reco.636.1193.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
46

Schwarz, Jiří. „The Economic history and the economics“. Acta Oeconomica Pragensia 13, Nr. 3 (01.10.2005): 152–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.18267/j.aop.155.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
47

Kharlamova, G., und V. Nesterenko. „ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS VS ECONOMIC(AL) ECOLOGY“. Bulletin of Taras Shevchenko National University of Kyiv Economics, Nr. 174 (2015): 83–98. http://dx.doi.org/10.17721/1728-2667.2015/174-9/14.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
48

Riley, Stephen T. „The Economic Consultant in Forensic Economics“. Journal of Forensic Economics 2, Nr. 3 (01.08.1989): 1–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.5085/0898-5510-2.3.1.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
49

Squires und Vestergaard. „Putting Economics into Maximum Economic Yield“. Marine Resource Economics 31, Nr. 1 (2016): 101. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/44011883.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
50

Ankarloo, Daniel. „New Institutional Economics and economic history“. Capital & Class 26, Nr. 3 (Oktober 2002): 9–36. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/030981680207800102.

Der volle Inhalt der Quelle
Annotation:
New Institutional Economics (NIE) has been celebrated as a path-breaking approach to the understanding of capitalism. This article advances a conceptual critique of NIE approaches to economic history. The author suggests that NIE cannot solve the underlying tension, that its economics remains ahistorical, and that when history, social relations and realism are invoked, the economics disappears, being replaced by various cultural and state-centred explanations. Therefore NIE is not so much a research programme in progress, but rather an indication of the degeneration of the tools of neo-classical economics.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO und andere Zitierweisen
Wir bieten Rabatte auf alle Premium-Pläne für Autoren, deren Werke in thematische Literatursammlungen aufgenommen wurden. Kontaktieren Sie uns, um einen einzigartigen Promo-Code zu erhalten!

Zur Bibliographie